[House Hearing, 110 Congress]
[From the U.S. Government Publishing Office]


 
                         USING FISCAL POLICY TO
                        BOLSTER THE U.S. ECONOMY

=======================================================================

                                HEARING

                               before the

                        COMMITTEE ON THE BUDGET
                        HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES

                       ONE HUNDRED TENTH CONGRESS

                             SECOND SESSION

                               __________

            HEARING HELD IN WASHINGTON, DC, JANUARY 29, 2008

                               __________

                           Serial No. 110-29

                               __________

           Printed for the use of the Committee on the Budget


                       Available on the Internet:
       http://www.gpoaccess.gov/congress/house/budget/index.html


                    U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
40-463                      WASHINGTON : 2008
_____________________________________________________________________________
For Sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office
Internet: bookstore.gpo.gov  Phone: toll free (866) 512-1800; (202) 512�091800  
Fax: (202) 512�092104 Mail: Stop IDCC, Washington, DC 20402�090001

                        COMMITTEE ON THE BUDGET

             JOHN M. SPRATT, Jr., South Carolina, Chairman
ROSA L. DeLAURO, Connecticut,        PAUL RYAN, Wisconsin,
CHET EDWARDS, Texas                    Ranking Minority Member
JIM COOPER, Tennessee                J. GRESHAM BARRETT, South Carolina
THOMAS H. ALLEN, Maine               JO BONNER, Alabama
ALLYSON Y. SCHWARTZ, Pennsylvania    SCOTT GARRETT, New Jersey
MARCY KAPTUR, Ohio                   MARIO DIAZ-BALART, Florida
XAVIER BECERRA, California           JEB HENSARLING, Texas
LLOYD DOGGETT, Texas                 DANIEL E. LUNGREN, California
EARL BLUMENAUER, Oregon              MICHAEL K. SIMPSON, Idaho
MARION BERRY, Arkansas               PATRICK T. McHENRY, North Carolina
ALLEN BOYD, Florida                  CONNIE MACK, Florida
JAMES P. McGOVERN, Massachusetts     K. MICHAEL CONAWAY, Texas
NIKI TSONGAS, Massachusetts          JOHN CAMPBELL, California
ROBERT E. ANDREWS, New Jersey        PATRICK J. TIBERI, Ohio
ROBERT C. ``BOBBY'' SCOTT, Virginia  JON C. PORTER, Nevada
BOB ETHERIDGE, North Carolina        RODNEY ALEXANDER, Louisiana
DARLENE HOOLEY, Oregon               ADRIAN SMITH, Nebraska
BRIAN BAIRD, Washington              [Vacancy]
DENNIS MOORE, Kansas
TIMOTHY H. BISHOP, New York
GWEN MOORE, Wisconsin

                           Professional Staff

            Thomas S. Kahn, Staff Director and Chief Counsel
                 Austin Smythe, Minority Staff Director


                            C O N T E N T S

                                                                   Page
Hearing held in Washington, DC, January 29, 2008.................     1

Statement of:
    Hon. John M. Spratt, Jr., Chairman, House Committee on the 
      Budget.....................................................     1
    Hon. Paul Ryan, ranking minority member, House Committee on 
      the Budget.................................................     2
    Lawrence H. Summers, Charles Eliot University Professor, 
      Harvard University.........................................     3
        Prepared statement of....................................     5
    Alice M. Rivlin, Ph.D., the Brookings Institution............     8
        Prepared statement of....................................    11
    Robert Greenstein, executive director, Center on Budget and 
      Policy Priorities..........................................    13
        Prepared statement of....................................    16
    Brian S. Wesbury, chief economist, First Trust Portfolios LP.    20
        Prepared statement of....................................    22


                         USING FISCAL POLICY TO
                        BOLSTER THE U.S. ECONOMY

                              ----------                              


                       TUESDAY, JANUARY 29, 2008

                          House of Representatives,
                                   Committee on the Budget,
                                                    Washington, DC.
    The committee met, pursuant to call, at 10:05 a.m., in room 
210, Cannon House Office Building, Hon. John Spratt [chairman 
of the committee] presiding.
    Present: Representatives Spratt, DeLauro, Edwards, Cooper, 
Kaptur, Becerra, Doggett, Blumenauer, Etheridge, Ryan, Garrett, 
Hensarling, and Conaway.
    Chairman Spratt. I call the hearing to order, and the first 
order of business is to recognize that we have a birthday among 
us. My colleague, Mr. Ryan, has reached the ripe old age of 38 
years. Happy birthday, Paul.
    Mr. Ryan. Thank you, Chairman. I'm still 4 months younger 
than Brett Favre. Mr. Chairman, thank you.
    Chairman Spratt. Well, good morning to everyone, and excuse 
my voice, but I've got a terrible cold. Welcome to the Budget 
Committee's hearing on the economy and what we can do to 
improve the prospects of near-term growth.
    We are pleased to have a panel of very distinguished 
economists to testify today. It includes Larry Summers, the 
former Secretary of the Treasury; Alice Rivlin, the founding 
Director of the Congressional Budget Office, and former Deputy 
Director of OMB; Bob Greenstein, the Executive Director of the 
Center on Budget and Policy Priorities; and Brian Wesbury, 
Chief Economist of First Trust Advisors.
    This hearing comes in response to warnings issued last 
December by Larry Summers and Marty Feldstein. Dr. Summers not 
only pointed to troubling conditions in the economy; he 
outlined a solution and suggested three Ts as our criteria for 
seeking such a solution: that it be timely, targeted and 
temporary.
    The need for countercyclical measures to shore up the 
economy was underscored by Marty Feldstein in testifying before 
this committee and reiterated by Chairman Bernanke and by CBO 
Director Orszag in hearings before this committee.
    Chairman Bernanke painted a worsening picture of current 
conditions and affirmed the need for fiscal stimulus to 
complement the monetary issues of the Federal Reserve. Dr. 
Bernanke and Dr. Orszag both projected a slowdown in growth but 
came short of predicting a recession. CBO's economic forecast, 
however, has grown more pessimistic since August, resulting in 
higher deficits in 2008 and a 10-year forecast that has 
worsened by $850 billion.
    Going straight to the bottom line, we have taken heed of 
your warnings. Later today, the House will take up bipartisan 
stimulus legislation that is consistent with the criteria 
suggested by Dr. Summers. It is timely. It is targeted. It is 
temporary. I hope very much that the House gives its 
overwhelming approval to this bill and sends it to the Senate, 
in which it is passed.
    This agreement is a practical step to boost the economy, to 
bolster consumer confidence and to give relief to millions of 
hardworking Americans where it is needed most. As with any 
compromise, no one got everything that he or she wanted in this 
package, but it is critical to get a bill enacted quickly, in 
order to help the economy and people who are hurting, without 
undue delay. I can name features that I would very much like to 
add to the bill, but expedition, I believe, is more important 
than any of them. I think that their coming to the floor is 
probably the best agreement we can strike with the Bush 
administration if we want the stimulus to come quickly and be 
effective.
    Over the weeks ahead, the Congress will continue to advance 
proposals to improve our security and strengthen the fiscal 
fundamentals. In light of the dismal economic news in the 2009 
budget resolution, we would appreciate your thoughts on the 
following questions: Where are we now? How did we get here? And 
where are we headed?
    Dr. Summers, we will ask you to lead off as the lead 
witness, but before turning to you for testimony, I want to 
recognize Mr. Ryan for his opening remarks.
    Mr. Ryan.
    Mr. Ryan. Thank you, Chairman.
    Chairman Spratt, you're three for three. Once again, 
today's hearing is both right on topic and extremely well-
timed, so I congratulate you for yet another interesting, well-
timed hearing.
    Just last week, the House leadership and the administration 
announced agreement on a bipartisan economic stimulus package. 
However, I understand that the Senate may move to alter that 
package with added spending. So today's hearing is an excellent 
opportunity for this committee to review the relative merit of 
various growth proposals.
    First, we have got to take a realistic look at the so-
called ``stimulus package'' and make sure we don't overestimate 
its effects. We must recognize the limits of the Federal 
Government's ability, particularly that of Congress, to address 
the immediate economic concerns at hand. Admittedly, I'm 
somewhat skeptical that Congress can get it right.
    These ``stimulus packages,'' which are the subject of the 
vagaries of the legislative process, tend to bear a much closer 
resemblance to a blunt instrument than the fine precision tool 
we pretend them to be.
    Even if we move quickly to enact this current growth 
package, for example, most analysts say the checks would go out 
around May or June in the third quarter. By then, the economic 
slowdown we seem to be experiencing could be over, at least 
according to current projections.
    I agree that letting taxpayers keep more of their own money 
that they've earned is a very good idea, especially now when it 
can provide a brief financial cushion at a time of high gas 
prices, high home heating prices and others. But at best, I 
think this action will have a small, short-lived impact.
    This package is clearly not a substitute for good economic 
policy. The key to long-term growth lies in expanding our 
economy's productive capacity, not in simply propping up short-
term demand by giving up resources the economy has already 
produced. For sustained economic growth, we need low tax 
burdens, a stable rate of inflation, an attractive investment 
climate, and a dynamic labor force. Growth also requires tax 
certainty so that American businesses and families can plan for 
the future.
    Finally, we have got to recognize that we simply cannot 
spend our way to prosperity. Congress will be tempted to use 
the excuse of ``fiscal stimulus'' to push through a wish list 
of new spending, and I compliment House leadership and the 
administration for resisting this temptation. It is ironic to 
hear increased government spending touted as a cure for our 
economic ills when it is unsustainable growth in government 
spending, particularly that of our entitlement programs, that 
pose the greatest threat to our Nation's long-term economic 
growth and prosperity. While there are risks to the short-term 
economic growth outlook, we need to balance these risks with 
the actions we take.
    I hope today's hearing will shed more light on the economic 
outlook and the effectiveness of steps to address these 
concerns about a weaker economy, and I thank the Chairman for 
his well-timed hearing.
    Chairman Spratt. Thank you, Mr. Ryan.
    Before proceeding, as a matter of housekeeping, I would 
like to ask unanimous consent that all members be allowed to 
submit an opening statement for the record at this point.
    And let me say a brief apology to Dr. Rivlin. I believe you 
were the Director of OMB, not just the Deputy Director. But, 
for the record, I want to recognize you for that.
    Let's proceed, then, with Dr. Summers.
    Dr. Summers, as with all the witnesses, your prefiled 
written testimony will be made part of the record. You can 
summarize it as you see fit. Thank you for coming. We look 
forward to hearing from you.

   STATEMENT OF LAWRENCE H. SUMMERS, PH.D., CHARLES W. ELIOT 
            UNIVERSITY PROFESSOR, HARVARD UNIVERSITY

    Mr. Summers. Mr. Chairman, thank you very much for the 
opportunity to appear before this distinguished committee at 
this important juncture. Let me make three points.
    First, the most likely course for the American economy now 
appears to be that the economy will go into recession during 
2008. In that context, fiscal stimulus is appropriate. There is 
the possibility, though very much not a probability, that with 
an inadequate policy response, a recession could be protracted 
as a vicious cycle starts in which financial strains lead to 
reduced spending, which leads to a weaker economy, which leads 
to increased financial strains, which leads to a weaker economy 
and so forth, creating a vicious cycle. This risk is present 
and makes action appropriate.
    Second, the actions--the proposed stimulus package agreed 
by the congressional leadership--House leadership and the 
President meets the necessary criteria for fiscal stimulus. It 
is, given the circumstances, timely; and, I might say to many, 
it came as a very pleasant surprise how rapidly that agreement 
was reached. And one hopes that the momentum from that will be 
confirmed today when the House votes, and in the very near 
future as this moves forward in the Senate.
    It is, for the most part, appropriately targeted in 
directions that are likely to spur spending and cause the money 
to be injected into the economy as rapidly as possible; and, 
appropriately, it is temporary and focused on the near-term 
issue of providing stimulus. There is no possible improvement 
in this package that would warrant a substantial delay in its 
passage.
    That said, like everyone else, I would prefer to see 
changes in the package, but proposed changes are very much 
subordinate to the imperative of rapid action.
    The two changes that I would most like to see are the 
inclusion of an expansion in unemployment insurance benefits, 
which, in my judgment, would respond appropriately to the fact 
that we have very substantial levels of long-term unemployment 
today, that the unemployed are the people who are likely to 
spend money most rapidly upon its receipt so as to have maximum 
impact, and the increases in benefit levels can take place even 
more rapidly than the provision of tax rebates.
    The second change I would like to see, which would make it 
possible to pay for the first change within the current budget 
envelope, would be the modification of the proposed business 
tax breaks to operate on an incremental basis. The business tax 
break of accelerated depreciation has as its motivation that it 
will encourage the rescheduling of investment from 2009 or 2010 
into 2008 when that investment is most needed. If the incentive 
was provided not for all investment in 2008, but only for 
investment above two-thirds of last year's investment, or above 
depreciation, or above some form of benchmark, as is done with 
the R&D tax credit, exactly the same incentive would be 
provided at a cost of only about a third as great to the fisc, 
making it possible to expand rebates or to expand unemployment 
insurance.
    Both of these steps would, in my judgment, make for a 
better package, but neither is worth substantial delay in the 
current context.
    Third and finally, Mr. Chairman, I would emphasize that the 
danger of recession and the appropriateness of stimulus as a 
response to that recession should not blind anyone. It 
especially should not blind members of this committee to the 
very substantial, long-run fiscal problems that this country 
continues to face.
    At the root of many of our economic difficulties is our low 
level of national saving, and at the root of our low level of 
national saving is the activities that take place in the 
Federal budget. It is not unreasonable to project--given the 
various items such as the AMT, such as increased war costs not 
included in the standard Congressional Budget Office baseline 
and the reality that the Congressional Budget Office has 
estimated--that recessions typically lead to reduced revenues 
and increased expenditures that would at the current scale of 
the economy amount to extra costs of $150 to $300 billion or 
more; that in the event of the recession that is likely to 
materialize, we will within a couple of years be facing budget 
deficits that could be $500 billion or more.
    This is a very tentative forecast, and it could easily not 
materialize. But it highlights the importance of regarding the 
nonuse of PAYGO as something that is very specific and 
appropriate to this fiscal stimulus package at this moment, but 
it underscores the importance for the remainder of this year 
and, I would suggest, the likely importance at the beginning of 
next year of this committee focusing, as it has so often in the 
past, on the long-term health of our budget.
    Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
    Chairman Spratt. Thank you very much, Dr. Summers.
    [The prepared statement of Lawrence Summers follows:]

  Prepared Statement of Lawrence H. Summers, Charles Eliot University 
                     Professor, Harvard University

    I am grateful for the opportunity to testify before this committee 
at this important juncture. I admire last week's efforts by the 
President, the Treasury Secretary, and both parties of the House to 
reach a deal on a stimulus package that is timely, targeted, and 
temporary. A similar urgency in the Senate this week will hopefully 
produce the stimulus this economy requires and will help average 
Americans to get through this period of economic uncertainty. Here I 
answer six questions concerning the major issues at stake in the debate 
over fiscal stimulus, and then provide my views on the stimulus 
agreement reached last week. While I will attempt to provide the most 
definitive answers as of this moment, the best policy response may 
change as we receive new economic data and as our understanding of the 
current, highly volatile economic situation improves.

                1. what is the current economic outlook?

    Following the instability in global markets last week and recent 
economic reports--particularly the last employment report and retail 
sales data--my judgment, like that of many economists, is that a 
recession is more likely than not. Even if there is not an officially 
defined recession, there is almost certain to be a significant slowdown 
in the economy that will feel like a recession in many parts of the 
country and to many businesses and families. Moreover given the 
extraordinary fragility observed in financial markets at present, there 
is a risk of a dangerous situation developing in which financial 
strains create a weakening economy which in turn creates financial 
strains. Such a vicious cycle if not preempted could lead to a 
recession considerably worse than what we observed in in either 2001 or 
the early 1990s. In this context the preponderant economic risks are of 
recession and financial instability rather than inflation and asset 
price bubbles.

 2. why not rely on monetary policy to stimulate the economy and focus 
                  fiscal policy on longer term issues?

    As Chairman Bernanke has recognized, monetary policy has an 
essential role to play in maintaining demand and growth as well as in 
combating financial instability. In the current context, however, it is 
best complemented by fiscal policy for a variety of reasons: (i) in 
normal times fiscal policy is faster acting than monetary policy, and 
given the financial problems it may be even more true today. (ii) 
proper fiscal policies can target the innocent victims of recession and 
can directly promote job creation, (iii) full reliance on monetary 
policy could easily mean lowering interest rates to levels that would 
be problematic for the dollar, commodity prices, future asset bubbles 
and moral hazard, and (iv) in a situation where policy impacts are 
uncertain it is most prudent to rely on a diversified set of stimulus 
measures. The Federal Reserve's unprecedented 75-basis-point 
intermeeting reduction constitutes an important step, but the goal of 
alleviating the likelihood of a recession--and moderating a recession 
if we do experience one--will be best achieved by complementing 
monetary policy with a fiscal stimulus. Failure to build on the 
progress made in the last weeks towards an agreed stimulus plan would 
be a significant blow to market confidence and economic prospects.

    3. how great is the risk of overheating the economy and causing 
   inflation? should a decision on fiscal stimulus await definitive 
               evidence that the economy is in recession?

    The balance of risks is now on the side of recession rather than 
inflation. Inflation measured by personal consumption expenditures 
excluding food and energy was 1.9 percent over the last year. Measures 
of inflation expectations as inferred from Treasury indexed bonds are 
close to their lowest point in the last two years. Moreover, in a 
climate of great uncertainty about workers' jobs and firms' profit 
margins inflation pressures are more likely to diminish than increase. 
Increases in inflation that have been observed recently reflect to a 
significant extent the impact of developments in oil as well as other 
commodity markets as well as declines in the dollar. Even if they are 
not reversed, these markets are unlikely have as large an inflationary 
impact in the future as in the recent past.
    There is sufficient weakness in the economy to justify stimulus 
legislation now with provision for rapid implementation. Studies of 
past experiences with stimulus reveal that too often stimulus comes too 
late. The risks of excessive delay given lags in implementation and 
effect are much greater than the risks of premature stimulus. If 
stimulus were to be excessive any highly speculative risks of 
overheating the economy could be offset by the Fed. On the other hand, 
allowing recessionary forces to build could be very dangerous as 
financial and real economic problems reinforced each other.

               4. how large should a stimulus package be?

    In December, I advocated stimulus in the range of $50-$75 billion. 
Given recent data, I now believe that it would be appropriate to enact 
a program of this magnitude as soon as possible and to make provision 
for a second tranche of about the same magnitude. While as recently as 
a few weeks ago, I would have favored some tranching of additional 
fiscal stimulus, adverse developments have been sufficient that I now 
believe that enacting a full package at once is the best course of 
action.
    Sizing a stimulus package cannot be reduced to hard science. Given 
the deterioration in the economy that has taken place in recent months 
a package with a total cost of 1% of GDP would run very little danger 
of overheating the economy on any plausible scenario. If delivered in 
the second and third quarters of 2008 it could have a material impact 
on consumers and on confidence more generally.

              5. what should comprise a stimulus package?

    As with any potent medicine, stimulus, if misadministered, could do 
more harm than good by increasing instability and creating long run 
problems.
    A stimulus program should be timely, targeted and temporary.
    Timely stimulus requires both that Congress and the President act 
quickly and that measures be chosen which can be implemented rapidly 
and which will have their ultimate impact on spending in short order. 
This puts a premium on simple measures that work through existing 
modalities, such as adjustment of withholding schedules, tax refunds, 
or enhancements of benefits. It calls into question the wisdom of 
designing new programs or using approaches where Federal spending is 
not injected fairly directly into the economy. When past stimulus 
efforts have failed, the major problem has been that they have come too 
late.
    Given the Olympic analogies that been infused into this election 
cycle in recent weeks, a medal system may be an appropriate rubric for 
quantifying the relative timeliness of various stimulus packages. A 
gold medal would go to legislation passed in the first quarter of this 
year, with its impact realized in the second and third quarters. A 
silver medal could be awarded for any legislation passed in the second 
quarter, with impact realized within the year. But because this is an 
Olympics of a different sort, no medal would be awarded for legislation 
enacted beyond the second quarter that does not have an impact this 
year.
    Targeted stimulus requires that funds be channeled where they will 
be spent rapidly and where they will reach those most in need. This 
also argues for use of simple changes in withholding schedules, or tax 
refunds, as well as for changes in benefit formulas. In general, 
targeting in both the sense of assuring maximum spending and fairness 
are likely to be achieved by measures that focus on those with low 
incomes and whose incomes have sharply declined.
    Temporary stimulus is necessary if stimulus is not to raise 
questions about the country's long run fiscal position. If stimulus 
were not credibly temporary, it would likely raise long term interest 
rates and increase capital costs offsetting its positive impact. 
Moreover if stimulus is not temporary, the risks that it will continue 
even after the economy recovers and lead to inflation or very high 
interest rates is greatly increased. Stimulus should be designed so 
that its proximate impact on consumer or government spending is all 
felt within a year of enactment and in any event by the end of the 
first quarter of 2009. If fiscal credibility is to be maintained, it is 
important also that no measures be enacted on a temporary basis that 
will generate overwhelming political pressures for their extension.
    On the tax side, these considerations suggest the desirability of 
across-the-board equal tax cuts or refunds for all tax-filers, as the 
President and House agreed last week. Measures which reduce taxes in 
proportion to taxes currently paid or that disproportionately favor 
upper income taxpayers or recipients of capital income are likely to be 
far less effective because such taxpayers spend much less of new income 
than low and moderate income taxpayers. Measures which commit today to 
reduce future taxes relative to current law are likely to be 
counterproductive because of the fiscal doubts they raise and because 
they do not provide liquidity now, which is precisely the moment when 
consumers are facing the need to cut back spending.
    From these perspectives, the proposal agreed by the House and 
Administration is a very valuable step forward. It is timely, targeted 
and temporary. I believe it could be improved however in two ways:
    Business incentives: As I stated previously, the case for business 
rebates is not compelling. The experience with the 2001 stimulus 
program is not very encouraging with respect to the efficacy of 
business incentives as stimulus. Nonetheless, a properly-targeted 
temporary investment tax credit or accelerated depreciation scheme 
might pull some investment forward from future years into 2008. To 
maximize the bang for the buck, such a program should be incremental 
and apply only to investment above some benchmark, such as \2/3\ of 
previous investment or depreciation.
    Increases in benefits: The agreement between the House and the 
President failed to adopt increases in benefits, such as unemployment 
insurance and food stamps, in spite of significant nonpartisan research 
championing them as the most efficient stimulus options. A recent study 
by the Congressional Budget Office found that out of all stimulus 
options, only unemployment benefits and food stamps were cost-effective 
in terms of the demand they generate relative to their cost, featured a 
short lag between enactment and realization of the stimulus effect, and 
could be predicted to be effective with substantial certainty. Such 
increases can be implemented quickly, and the benefits go to people who 
will spend them fast. In addition, these benefits provide assistance to 
the innocent victims of recession, the people who struggle most to pay 
heating bills, to pay their monthly credit card bills, and to stay 
employed so that they can support their families.

      6. should stimulus be paid for within a given budget window?

    Fiscal stimulus to an economy in recession operates by increasing 
demand in an economy that is constrained by lack of demand. If it is 
paid for contemporaneously, its point is largely lost as there is no 
net stimulus to demand because money injected in one area is withdrawn 
in another.
    As long as a fiscal stimulus program is temporary and does not 
create expectations of future spending or tax cuts, it does not make a 
large economic difference whether or not it is offset by specific 
future fiscal actions. Including offsets in a five or a ten year window 
would magnify the impact of fiscal stimulus a little bit by reducing 
any adverse impact on capital costs because it would avoid any 
increases in long run debt levels. But it would also run the risk of 
delay in providing stimulus as the Congress debated possible offsets.

7. what are the most important budgetary issues going forward after the 
                            stimulus debate?

    While stimulus is appropriate in the short run, the United States 
needs over the medum term to restors its fiscal health to the level of 
the 1990s. Deficit reduction is essential if capital costs are to be 
low enough to encourage healthy investment in the future of our 
economy. As part of the concern about deficit reduction, over time it 
will be necessary for Congress to look at among other things: (i) 
health care spending on a systematic national basis, (ii) Social 
Security and its actuarial soundness which has deteriorated in recent 
years; (iii) budget process issues (iv) tax evasion and avoidance among 
other things.

    Chairman Spratt. Dr. Rivlin.

    STATEMENT OF ALICE M. RIVLIN, PH.D., SENIOR FELLOW, THE 
                     BROOKINGS INSTITUTION

    Ms. Rivlin. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
    I am very happy to be here this morning to urge the 
Congress to enact the stimulus package quickly. I am not quite 
as gloomy as Larry, but frankly we don't know what is going to 
happen to the economy. I think a well-designed stimulus package 
is needed now as an insurance policy to reduce the risk of 
recession or mitigate its severity if it occurs. The compromise 
worked out by the President and the Speaker is well designed to 
stimulate spending quickly because it focuses on low- and 
moderate-income people, and I think it should be enacted as 
quickly as possible.
    I think the Congress should resist the temptation to delay 
the package by adding other elements, however worthy, and I 
would certainly think there are things that could have been 
added, but as you said earlier, nobody gets everything they 
want in a compromise.
    The risks posed by the package that it will aggravate 
inflation or add to the long-run deficit are real, but I think 
they are worth taking to help stabilize the economy in the 
months ahead. The economy slowed sharply in the fourth quarter 
of 2007, after growing strongly in the third, and the current 
quarter is beginning with signs of weakness as well.
    Unemployment rose in December, although 5 percent is still 
a pretty good number, and employment increase has stagnated. 
Retail sales have fallen off, and the housing sector continues 
to plunge. Although some indicators--notably exports--are 
positive, it is clear that the economy is in a period of slow 
growth and possibly headed for recession. Some economists are 
predicting a long or deep recession, including my colleague on 
the right. The gloomiest forecasts are coming from economists 
associated with major financial institutions, which is not 
surprising.
    The truth is we simply do not know. The economists are 
notoriously bad at predicting turning points in the economy and 
frequently overpredict recessions or miss their beginnings. The 
slowing economy is no surprise. Indeed, many were expecting it 
sooner, for reasons that I will skip over at the moment, but 
the economy is now being pummeled from above and below.
    In addition to the fallout from declining housing, rising 
foreclosure rates, we have seen massive losses to financial 
institutions on Wall Street and in other financial centers 
whose ultimate magnitude is still unclear, continuing 
uncertainty about the ultimate value of the assets backing many 
securities, and a sharp contraction in the willingness of 
financial institutions to lend, even to each other.
    The risks that the slowdown could be prolonged or turned 
into a serious downturn has clearly risen considerably in 
recent weeks. The Federal Reserve has moved aggressively to 
lower interest rates and infuse liquidity into the banking 
system. However, monetary policy may act slowly, and putting 
total reliance on monetary policy to stimulate spending carries 
some risk.
    Given recent experience with asset price bubbles, pushing 
interest rates towards zero, as the Federal Reserve did in 
response to the 2001 recession, seems like an invitation to 
another bubble, and widening the gap between interest rates in 
the U.S. and other currencies could cause a more rapid than 
desirable fall in the value of a dollar. Hence, it seems 
sensible to take out an insurance policy by adding a quick-
acting fiscal stimulus to the monetary stimulus already 
underway.
    The whole point of a stimulus package is to put money into 
the hands of people who will spend most of it when they get it, 
and the proposal, negotiated by the Speaker with the 
administration, is well designed to do that.
    The idea is, quite simply, to send checks to working people 
with low or moderate incomes. Under the proposal, everyone who 
earned $3,000 or more in 2007 would get $300, if you're 
familiar with the provisions of the proposal. The amounts are 
big enough to make a significant difference in consumption, 
especially for low-income families with children.
    The Center for Budget and Policy Priorities calculates that 
a couple with two children and earnings of $35,000 would get a 
rebate of $1,800. That is not insignificant. The plan phases 
out payments for those with incomes over $75,000, which allows 
the payments to be larger for a given total revenue loss, and 
more concentrated on low- and middle-income workers.
    The package is considerably more progressive than the plan 
originally floated by the administration, and at the top, it is 
more progressive than the proposal being discussed by Senator 
Baucus. The investment incentives in the package would add 
modest inducements for businesses to spend more on plant and 
equipment in 2008.
    The proposal also increases the loan limits for Fannie Mae, 
Freddie Mac and the Federal Housing Administration, which 
rising home prices in many areas have made obsolete. The 
formula would tie loan limits to median house prices in the 
metropolitan area. This new flexibility could help these 
entities operate more effectively to facilitate home financing 
and refinancing, especially in areas where prices rose most 
rapidly, and may avoid some foreclosures.
    I believe the government should intensify its efforts to 
work with lenders and community groups to keep families who 
have been making their payments in their homes, where possible; 
but these additional efforts do not belong in a stimulus 
package. Quick passage, I think, is more important than 
improvements, although improvements are possible.
    There are persuasive arguments for adding other elements to 
the proposed stimulus. Increasing food stamp benefits 
temporarily would get additional resources into the hands of 
very low-income people, including needy seniors, many of whom 
will be missed by the current proposal. Extending unemployment 
benefits by 13 or 26 weeks, which has been done in prior 
recessions, is especially appealing now, because long-term 
unemployment is disproportionately high.
    A strong case can be made for assisting the States most 
easily by increasing the Federal contribution to Medicaid. Such 
aid would help forestall State tax increases or benefit cuts, 
actions that States often take to balance their budgets in a 
slowing economy, and that tend to make recessions worse.
    Personally, I would favor all of these measures, especially 
if the economic indicators turn more negative, but I believe it 
would be a mistake to slow down enactment of the current 
proposal by adding controversial amendments to the package now. 
In particular, Congress should resist the temptation to add 
construction projects to the stimulus bill. Building and 
repairing infrastructure can contribute to long-run growth and 
productivity, but such projects spend out too slowly to provide 
economic stimulus in time to be an effective antidote to a 
recession.
    Is the stimulus package without risks? Of course not. With 
core consumer price inflation running somewhat above 2 percent 
and the threat of rising energy prices passing through to other 
prices, stimulus could add to inflationary pressure, especially 
if the slowing economy, as we all hope, turns around quickly. 
The inflationary risk appears small, however.
    In recent years, the economy has proved itself much less 
inflation-prone than it was when oil price surges led to 
stagflation in the 1970s. The American economy is more energy-
efficient, more flexible and competitive, more exposed to 
downward pressure on prices and wages in the global economy, 
and less unionized than in previous decades.
    As a result, inflation expectations, which can become self-
fulfilling prophesies, remain low. Moreover, the Federal 
Reserve, my former colleagues, which cherishes its credibility 
as an effective inflation fighter, can be counted on to keep a 
close eye on present trends and to suspend monetary easing if 
it detects a serious inflationary threat. The bigger risk, as 
Larry has emphasized, is that the stimulus package, especially 
with major add-ons, will exacerbate the already ominous, long-
run deficit picture.
    Looking ahead, the United States faces mounting spending 
pressures as the baby-boom generation retires and the growth of 
medical spending continues to rise faster than the economy can 
grow. The Congressional Budget Office's long-run projections 
show clearly that if past trends continue, spending for 
Medicaid, Medicare and Social Security alone will swell to 
equal the proportion of total economic output currently devoted 
to the whole Federal Government. The cost of fulfilling 
promises made under the three major entitlement programs has 
put the whole Federal budget on an unsustainable track and will 
force hard choices that the political system is simply not 
recognizing at present. Indeed, our high and rising debt 
already constrains Federal policy, including efforts to move 
aggressively against a recession.
    In this situation, is it irresponsible to enact a stimulus 
package that will add to the debt we are passing on to future 
taxpayers? I do not think so. I believe that the stimulus 
package should be paid for over a 5-year period. I was 
disappointed that you waived PAYGO for this. The PAYGO 
principle has never been more important, and it should be 
honored. Making exceptions can become a dangerous habit. 
Nevertheless, even if it is not subjected to the PAYGO rules, 
the proposed stimulus will not add significantly to the long-
run deficit problem. The rebates are one-shot payments with 
much less deficit impact than a permanent reduction in tax 
rates.
    Moreover, if the combination of monetary and fiscal policy 
is successful in stimulating the economy and attenuating the 
downturn, bigger increases in the deficit may be avoided. 
Hence, if Congress can resist the temptation to add spending 
increases or revenue losses to the stimulus package, I believe 
the deficit increase associated with the stimulus represents a 
risk worth taking in order to reduce the chances of recession 
or mitigate its impact.
    Thank you.
    Chairman Spratt. Thank you very much.
    [The prepared statement of Alice M. Rivlin follows:]

   Prepared Statement of Alice M. Rivlin, the Brookings Institution*

    Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee: I am happy to be here 
this morning to urge Congress to enact a stimulus package quickly. In 
brief, I believe that:
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    *The views expressed in this testimony are those of the author and 
should not be attributed to the staff, officers or trustees of the 
Brookings Institution.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
     A well-designed stimulus package is needed now as an 
insurance policy to reduce the risk of recession or mitigate its 
severity if it occurs;
     The compromise worked out by the President and Speaker 
Pelosi is well-designed to stimulate spending quickly, because it 
focuses on low- and moderate income people, and should be enacted as 
soon as possible;
     The Congress should resist the temptation to delay the 
package by adding other elements, however worthy, at this time;
     Risks posed by the package--that it will aggravate 
inflation or add to the long-run deficit--are worth taking to help 
stabilize the economy in the months ahead.
    I will elaborate briefly on each of these points.

                   WHY AN INSURANCE POLICY IS NEEDED

    The economy clearly slowed sharply in the fourth quarter of 2007 
after growing strongly in the third, and the current quarter is 
beginning with signs of weakness as well. Unemployment rose in 
December--although 5 percent is still a pretty good number--and 
employment increases stagnated. Retail sales have fallen off, and the 
housing sector continues to plunge. Although some indicators, notably 
exports, are positive, it is clear that the economy is in a period of 
slow growth, possibly headed for a recession. Some economists are 
predicting a long or deep recession. The gloomiest forecasts are coming 
from economists associated with major financial institutions. The truth 
is: we simply do not know. Economists are notoriously bad at predicting 
turning points in the economy and frequently over-predict recessions or 
miss their beginnings.
    The slowing of the economy is no surprise; indeed, many were 
expecting it sooner. The rapid increase in housing prices in many parts 
of the country, led to a big upswing in home building, some of it 
speculative. We simply built too many houses. When prices peaked and 
began to decline, housing construction fell off, construction workers 
were laid off, and the fall-out spread from the home construction, real 
estate, finance and insurance industries, to other sectors, especially 
in areas where house prices had risen most and home-building was 
frenetic. Consumers, who had been spending out of their rapidly-
increasing home equity, found it leveling off or falling and began to 
retrench.
    The housing boom was financed by the combination of low interest 
rates and a rapidly expanding market for mortgage-backed securities. 
Even without the explosion of sub-prime lending, the rapid upswing in 
housing construction and prices would have run its course and put some 
downward pressure on the economy. However, instead of a normal housing 
cycle we had a perfect storm--a lethal combination of historically low 
interest rates, widespread public conviction that housing prices could 
only go up, enthusiastic experimentation with sub-prime and other 
unfamiliar mortgage instruments, failure of the fragmented regulatory 
system to rein in irresponsible mortgage lending behavior, and failure 
of risk managers at financial institutions and rating agencies to 
anticipate the fall in value of mortgage-backed securities that would 
inevitably occur when housing prices peaked and foreclosure rates rose.
    The economy is now being pummeled from above and below. In addition 
to the fallout from declining housing and rising foreclosure rates, we 
have seen massive losses to financial institutions on Wall Street and 
in other financial centers, whose ultimate magnitude is still unclear, 
continuing uncertainty about the ultimate value of the assets backing 
many securities, and a sharp contraction in the willingness of 
financial institutions to lend--even to each other. The risk that the 
slowdown could be prolonged or turn into a serious downturn has clearly 
risen considerably in recent weeks.
    The Federal Reserve has moved aggressively to lower interest rates 
and infuse liquidity into the banking system. However, monetary policy 
may act slowly, and putting total reliance on monetary policy to 
stimulate spending carries some risk. Given recent experience with 
asset price bubbles, pushing interest rates toward zero, as the Federal 
Reserve did in response to the 2001 recession, seems like an invitation 
to another bubble, and widening the gap between interest rates in the 
U.S. and other currencies could cause a more rapid than desirable fall 
in the value of the dollar. Hence, it seems sensible to take out an 
insurance policy by adding a quick-acting fiscal stimulus to the 
monetary stimulus already underway.

                   STRENGTHS OF THE PROPOSED PACKAGE

    The whole point of a stimulus package is to put money into the 
hands of people who will spend most of it when they get it, and the 
proposal negotiated by the Speaker with the Administration is well 
designed to do that. The idea is quite simply to send checks to working 
people with low or moderate incomes. Under the proposal everyone who 
earned $3000 or more in 2007 would get $300 ($600 per couple plus $300 
per child), even if they did not earn enough to pay income tax. Those 
who did pay income tax would get up to $300 ($600 per couple) more. The 
amounts are big enough to make a significant difference in consumption, 
especially for low income families with children. The Center for Budget 
and Policy Priorities calculates that a couple with two children and 
earnings of $35,000 would get a rebate of $1800. The plan phases out 
payments for those with incomes over $75,000 ($150,000 per couple), 
which allows the payments to be larger (for a given total revenue loss) 
and more concentrated on low- and middle-income workers. The package is 
considerably more progressive than the plan originally floated by the 
Administration.
    The investment incentives in the package would add modest 
inducements for businesses to spend more on plant and equipment in 
2008. The proposal also increases the loan limits for Fannie Mae, 
Freddie Mac, and the Federal Housing Administration (FHA), which rising 
home prices in many areas had made obsolete. The formula would tie the 
loan limits to median house prices in the metropolitan area. This new 
flexibility should help these entities operate more effectively to 
facilitate home financing and refinancing, especially in areas where 
prices rose most rapidly, and may avoid some foreclosures. (I believe 
the government should intensify its efforts to work with lenders and 
community groups to keep families who have been making their payments 
in their homes where possible. But these additional efforts do not 
belong in a stimulus package.)

            QUICK PASSAGE IS MORE IMPORTANT THAN IMPROVEMENT

    There are persuasive arguments for adding other elements to the 
proposed stimulus. Increasing Food Stamp benefits temporarily would get 
additional resources into the hands of very low income people, 
including needy seniors, many of whom will be missed by the current 
proposal. Extending unemployment benefits by 13 or 26 weeks, which has 
been done in prior recessions, is especially appealing now, because 
long-term unemployment is disproportionately high. A strong case can be 
made for assisting the states, most easily by increasing the federal 
contribution to Medicaid. Such aid would help forestall state tax 
increases or benefit cuts--actions that states often take to balance 
their budgets in a slowing economy and that tend to make recessions 
worse. Personally, I would favor all these measures, especially if the 
economic indicators turn more negative, but I believe it would be a 
mistake to slow down enactment of the current proposal by adding 
controversial amendments to the package now.
    In particular, Congress should resist the temptation to add 
construction projects to the stimulus bill. Building and repairing 
infrastructure can contribute to long-run growth and productivity, but 
such projects spend out too slowly to provide economic stimulus in time 
to be an effective antidote to recession.

                     WHY THE RISKS ARE WORTH TAKING

    Is a stimulus package without risk? Of course not! With core 
consumer price inflation running somewhat above 2 percent and the 
threat that rising energy prices will cause other price increases to 
accelerate, stimulus could add to inflationary pressure, especially if 
the slowing economy turns around quickly. The inflationary risk appears 
small, however. In recent years, the economy has proved itself much 
less inflation prone than it was when oil price surges led to 
stagflation in the 1970's. The American economy is more energy-
efficient, more flexible and competitive, more exposed to downward 
pressures on prices and wages in the global economy, and less unionized 
than in previous decades. As a result inflation expectations, which can 
become self-fulfilling prophesies, remain low. Moreover, the Federal 
Reserve, which cherishes its credibility as an effective inflation 
fighter, can be counted on to keep a close eye on price trends and to 
suspend monetary easing if it detects a serious inflationary threat.
    The bigger risk is that the stimulus package, especially with major 
add-ons, will exacerbate the already ominous long-run deficit picture. 
Looking ahead, the United States faces mounting spending pressures as 
the baby boom generation retires and the growth of medical spending 
continues to rise faster than the economy can grow. The Congressional 
Budget Office's long run budget projections show clearly that, if past 
trends continue, spending for Medicare, Medicaid and Social Security 
alone will swell to equal the proportion of total economic output 
currently devoted to the whole federal government. The cost of 
fulfilling promises made under the three major entitlement programs has 
put the whole federal budget on an unsustainable track and will force 
hard choices that the political system is simply not recognizing at 
present. Indeed, our high and rising debt already constrains federal 
policy, including efforts to move aggressively against recession. In 
this situation is it irresponsible to enact a stimulus package that 
will add to the debt that we are passing on to future taxpayers?
    I believe that the stimulus package should be paid for over a five-
year period. The PAYGO principle has never been more important and 
should be honored. Making exceptions can become a dangerous habit. 
Nevertheless, even if it is not subjected to the PAYGO rules, the 
proposed stimulus will not add significantly to the long-run deficit 
problem. The rebates are one-shot payments with much less deficit 
impact than a permanent reduction in tax rates. Moreover, if the 
combination of monetary and fiscal policy is successful in stimulating 
the economy and attenuating a downturn, bigger increases in the deficit 
may be avoided. Hence, if Congress can resist the temptation to add 
permanent spending increases or revenue losses to the stimulus package, 
I believe the deficit increase associated with the stimulus represents 
a risk worth taking in order to reduce the chances of recession or 
mitigate its impact.
    Thank you for listening. I would be happy to answer questions.

    Chairman Spratt. Mr. Greenstein.

 STATEMENT OF ROBERT GREENSTEIN, EXECUTIVE DIRECTOR, CENTER ON 
                  BUDGET AND POLICY PRIORITIES

    Mr. Greenstein. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
    As you know, in the past, stimulus packages often came too 
late, contained measures that were not timely targeted, 
temporary, or both. You are certainly off to a good start. At 
this point, you will be voting, I believe today, on a package 
that I certainly hope you will pass. The Senate Finance 
Committee will be marking up tomorrow, and the Chairman's mark, 
announced yesterday, contains some provisions that I think 
would further strengthen the stimulative effects of the 
package. It may be on the Senate floor by Thursday, and I hope 
you will be able to pass it and send it to the President before 
the President's Day recess.
    In a hearing in the last week or so at the Senate Finance 
Committee, Martin Feldstein noted that in the current context, 
in an economy where there is extra slack, we really do want to 
increase consumer spending. I would like to talk for a couple 
of minutes about how most effectively to do that.
    As the Congressional Budget Office and other economists 
such as Larry Summers have noted, stimulus measures are more 
effective when they are focused on lower-income households than 
higher-income households because people who live paycheck to 
paycheck tend to spend rather than save nearly all of the added 
income. Analyses of the 2001 tax rebates found that lower-
income households spent a larger share of the rebates than more 
affluent households did.
    This strongly suggests that the bipartisan House leaders 
made a wise decision last week when they included most low-
income working families in the tax rebates. It also points to a 
way in which the stimulus package could be strengthened, 
hopefully, in the Senate.
    Under the House package, working poor families will receive 
considerably smaller rebates than more well-off families. A 
mother with one child, who works full time at the minimum wage 
and makes about $12,000 a year, will get a rebate of $600, 
while a family of the same size, say a married couple making 
$150,000 a year, will get a rebate of $1,200, or twice as much. 
The rebates would be more effective as stimulus if the rebate 
amounts were uniform, a point, I think, Larry Summers has been 
making for the past month in various forums.
    Senator Baucus' mark, announced yesterday, would remedy 
that by making the rebates uniform, so the working poor 
families would get the same size as middle- or upper middle-
income families, and it also includes an element under the 
current House package. Middle-income elderly would get rebates, 
but lower-income elderly would not, and under his mark, lower-
income elderly and middle-income elderly are both in.
    Now, one limitation of the rebates is that they will take 
some time to work. The first rebate checks apparently can't go 
out until late May, and many families won't receive their 
rebates until July, or possibly early August. The whole point 
of moving so quickly is to start injecting demand into the 
economy as quickly as you can. And I, therefore, think it would 
be very useful--and I am echoing Larry's analysis here--very 
useful to include in the package--again, this could be done in 
the Senate--two provisions that most experts agree would be 
highly effective as stimulus and are the two most fast-acting 
options on the table. These, of course, are the provisions 
related to unemployment insurance and food stamps.
    In CBO's recent report on stimulus options, the 
unemployment insurance and food stamp options are the only 
items that receive CBO's top rating in all three of CBO's 
categories for evaluating stimulus options. CBO said these two 
options would, one, have large effects on a bang-for-the-buck 
basis; two, only a short time lag between enactment and the 
time by which the policy has achieved the bulk of its 
stimulative effect; and, three, carry only a small degree of 
uncertainty as to the stimulative effects. Now, if you look at 
the CBO report, you find that no other tax or spending options 
CBO evaluated gets CBO's top rating for even two of these 
categories, let alone all three.
    In an analysis on Friday, Goldman Sachs made essentially 
the same point. And MoodysEconomy.com published an analysis 
last week, looking at the various options, and it found the 
following: It estimated that a temporary increase in food stamp 
benefits would generate $1.73 in increased economic activity 
for each dollar in cost; unemployment insurance, $1.64 per 
dollar in cost; the tax rebates, $1.26 for each dollar in cost; 
and the bonus depreciation tax cut, which is in the package, 27 
cents in increased economic activity per dollar of cost.
    The reason the UI and food stamp provisions rate so highly 
as stimulus is clear. They target people who either have very 
low incomes and spend every dollar they get, or are facing 
large declines in income because they've lost their jobs, and 
their unemployment benefits are running out, and if they don't 
get a continuation, there will be a big drop in consumption. 
They also are the two items that can be implemented most 
rapidly.
    For example, to take food stamps, a topic I know 
particularly well, an increase in food stamp benefits can be 
implemented in 30 to 60 days after enactment, as early as April 
1st in some States, and studies show that 97 percent of the 
benefits are spent by the end of the month. I think that is why 
such people as from Martin Feldstein, to Larry in his written 
testimony today, Alice as you've just heard, all rate food 
stamps as one of the most effective things you can do.
    Now, as you know, the Chairman's mark in the Senate does 
include an unemployment insurance provision. Food stamps may be 
considered on the Senate floor.
    One final issue, although I think this final issue is 
probably not for the current package--none of you would think 
of raising taxes now or paying for a stimulus package with 
simultaneous tax increases or spending cuts that would take 
effect right now. That would be a drag on the economy. Bad 
idea. Yet we are headed for large budget cuts and tax increases 
at State and local levels across the country, and those actions 
will be a drag on the economy. They will offset a portion of 
the effect of the Federal stimulus package.
    As you know, States are required to balance their budgets, 
even in recessions, so they raise taxes and cut spending in 
recession. The majority of States are now reporting budget 
deficits for fiscal year 09, which starts July 1 in most 
States, and those numbers are rising as more Governors bring 
out their budgets each week. It does look like large State 
budget cuts and tax increases are in store. Two States have 
already enacted large tax increases to close projected 
deficits. Governors and legislative leaders in a growing number 
of States are proposing hefty cuts in areas ranging from 
reducing health coverage of low-income children to education 
and other basic services. In the last downturn, for example, 
State Medicaid cuts led to the loss of health care coverage for 
about a million low-income people, and aggravating the problem 
right now are falling property tax revenues as a result of 
declining home values.
    In my view, this suggests that if not now--which doesn't 
look like it is going to happen--then in the not-too-distant 
future, Congress really ought to pay attention to this and 
provide some fiscal relief to lessen the degree to which States 
take contractionary actions that slow the economy.
    I would note--this is with a little disappointment--that 
the current stimulus package does make this problem somewhat 
worse in that the bonus depreciation tax cut in the package 
will cause 30 States to lose $4 billion in revenue because of 
linkages between Federal and State tax codes. The States will 
have to raise taxes or cut budgets somewhat more.
    Now, in conclusion, the current work on the stimulus 
package is off to a very promising start. It is my hope you 
will pass the package today. It is my hope that it can be 
strengthened in the Senate without causing any delay. I agree 
on the need for fast action, and hopefully within 10 days or 
so, a good package can be on its way to the President.
    Thank you.
    Chairman Spratt. Thank you, Bob Greenstein.
    [The prepared statement of Robert Greenstein follows:]

Prepared Statement of Robert Greenstein, Executive Director, Center on 
                      Budget and Policy Priorities

    I appreciate the invitation to testify before the Committee. I am 
Robert Greenstein, director of the Center on Budget and Policy 
Priorities, a policy institute that specializes in fiscal policy as 
well as in policies related to low- and moderate-income families. The 
Center does not, and never has, received any federal grants or 
contracts.
    I would like to start with some observations about the importance 
of taking business cycles into account when evaluating fiscal policy 
options. The economy always grows--and revenue always increases--during 
economic recoveries and periods of normal economic growth. Sometimes 
this may lead to mistaken assumptions that certain policies whose 
adoption coincided with the start of a recovery caused the recovery or 
the resulting revenue growth. Thus, a claim is often made that the tax 
cuts enacted at the start of this decade caused the recovery and the 
revenue growth of recent years, or at least made the growth much 
greater than it otherwise would have been. The same logic, however, 
could be used to argue that the tax increases enacted in 1990 and 1993 
caused the boom of the 1990s. Neither claim is especially credible.\1\ 
I also would note that during the recovery of recent years, which now 
appears to be ending, both economic and revenue growth were actually 
slower than during the recovery of the 1990s, and also slower than the 
average for comparable business-cycle periods since the end of World 
War II. That further weakens the case that the tax cuts of 2001 and 
2003 spurred strong growth.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    \1\ As Robert Hall of the Hoover Institution has noted, ``The U.S. 
economy recovered from every single recession it ever had, so the 
growth in 2003-2006 was generally part of the normal cyclical 
recovery.'' See Daniel Altman, ``Did the Tax Cuts Bolster Growth?,'' 
New York Times, May 13, 2007.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    Issues related to economic cycles are important again at the 
present time, as we think about appropriate measures to stimulate the 
economy and keep it out of recession (or to prevent a recession from 
becoming more severe). This is because the types of policy measures 
that are needed to stimulate the economy in the short term are very 
different from the policies one would want to pursue to improve 
prospects for long-term growth.
    For the long term, we need more saving and less consumption, 
policies to avert the persistent, large deficits that loom in future 
decades, and appropriate investments in things that can boost 
productivity such as education, basic research, and infrastructure. In 
contrast, what we need now is to keep consumption as strong as 
possible, rather than to increase saving. And various investments and 
other policies that may be useful for long term growth will not 
constitute effective stimulus in the short term, unless they inject 
increased demand into the economy quickly.
    Similarly, while ongoing tax cuts and entitlement increases should 
be fully paid for, it would not make sense to offset temporary stimulus 
measures by cutting programs or raising taxes in the same year, since 
doing so would diminish the stimulus effects.

                         WHAT SHOULD WE DO NOW?

    So what should we do now to stimulate the economy? As Martin 
Feldstein told the Senate Finance Committee last week, ``In the current 
context, in an economy where there's extra slack * * * we really do 
want to increase consumer spending.''
    The primary consumers are U.S. households. They are not the only 
consumers, however. Businesses and governments buy goods and services 
as well. We should pay attention to all three.

                           HOUSEHOLD SPENDING

    As the Congressional Budget Office and other economists have noted, 
stimulus measures that put more income into people's pockets are more 
effective when focused on low-income households, and less effective 
when focused on high-income households. This is because people who live 
paycheck to paycheck tend to spend, rather than save, nearly all of 
their added income, while those at high income levels would tend to 
bank much of it. Analyses of the 2001 tax rebates show that lower-
income households spent a larger share of their rebates than affluent 
households did.
    This suggests that House leaders made the right decision last week 
when they included most low-income working families in the tax rebates 
that they designed. Excluding such families would have made the rebate 
significantly less effective as economic stimulus. A recent analysis by 
Moody's Economy.com estimates that a rebate that fully includes such 
families would be 24 percent more effective as stimulus than a rebate 
that excludes these families (generating $1.26 in increased economic 
activity per dollar of cost, as compared to $1.02 for a rebate that 
leaves these families out).
    This also points, however, to a shortcoming in the rebate design. 
Under the agreement announced last week, working-poor families would 
receive considerably smaller rebates than more well-off families. Thus, 
a mother with one child who works full time at the minimum wage and 
makes less than $12,000 would receive a rebate of $600, while a married 
couple making $150,000 would receive a rebate of $1,200--or twice as 
much. The rebates would be more effective as stimulus if the rebate 
amounts were uniform, with the rebates that working-poor families 
receive being the same size, rather than smaller, than the rebates 
going to families at higher income levels.

                         TWO MISSING COMPONENTS

    One limitation of the rebates is that they will take some time to 
work. The first rebate checks apparently can not go out until late May, 
and many families will not receive their rebates until July or possibly 
early August. Yet the reason that House leaders and the Administration 
sought to move so expeditiously was to inject increased demand into the 
economy quickly.
    Therefore, I believe it was a mistake to drop the only two 
provisions that most experts agree would be both highly effective as 
stimulus and fast-acting--the provisions related to unemployment 
insurance and food stamps. In CBO's recent report on stimulus options, 
the unemployment insurance and food stamp options are the only items 
that receive CBO's top rating in all three of CBO's categories for 
evaluating the various options. CBO found that these two options would:
     have ``large'' effects in generating increased economic 
activity per dollar of cost;
     entail only a ``short'' lag between enactment and the time 
by which the policy has achieved the bulk of its stimulative effect; 
and
     carry only a ``small'' degree of uncertainty as to the 
policy's stimulus effects.
    No other tax or spending option received CBO's top rating in even 
two of the three categories, let alone all three.
    A number of private financial analysts have reached similar 
conclusions. In an analysis issued Friday, Goldman Sachs essentially 
made these same points and counseled that temporary increases in UI and 
food stamps have ``strong policy justifications'' as stimulus.\2\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    \2\ Goldman Sachs, ``Refilling the Punch Bowl: The Prospects for 
Fiscal Stimulus,'' Jan. 25, 2008.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    Similarly, an analysis issued last week by Moody's Economy.com, 
which examined the effectiveness of various stimulus options, gave its 
highest rating for effectiveness to the food stamp and UI options. The 
analysis found that:
     A temporary increase in food stamp benefits would generate 
$1.73 in increased economic activity for each $1 in cost.
     Extending unemployment benefits so workers' benefits do 
not run out before they find a new job would be the second most 
effective measure, generating $1.64 in increased activity per dollar of 
cost.
     By comparison, tax rebates that fully include low- and 
moderate-income working families would generate $1.26 in increased 
economic activity per dollar of cost.
     And the principal business tax cut in the new stimulus 
package--a proposal to accelerate the depreciation write-offs that 
firms take--would generate 27 cents in increased economic activity per 
dollar of cost.
    There are two reasons why the UI and food stamp provisions rate so 
highly as stimulus. First, these provisions would help people who 
either have very low incomes and are extremely cash constrained, or who 
otherwise face a precipitous decline in income because they have lost 
their jobs and now face the expiration of their unemployment benefits 
(and may cut their consumption sharply as a consequence). Because the 
food stamp and UI provisions are targeted on these groups, most of the 
resources that these provisions would provide to families would be 
spent quickly. The second reason these provisions rate highly is that 
they can be implemented rapidly.
    Take food stamps as an example. Food stamp households are poor--90 
percent of them live in poverty--and research has found that about 80 
percent of food stamp benefits are spent within two weeks of a 
household's receiving them. Some 97 percent of the benefits are spent 
by the end of the month. Furthermore, an increase in food stamp 
benefits can be implemented in 30-60 days after enactment, depending on 
the state.
    There also is a point about unemployment benefits worth noting. The 
long-term unemployment rate--the percentage of people in the workforce 
who have been unemployed for at least 26 weeks and are still looking 
for work--was nearly twice as high in the last quarter of 2007 as it 
was immediately before the 2001 recession. This is significant both 
because it is the long-term unemployed who reduce their consumption the 
most and because stimulus measures that provide additional weeks of 
unemployment benefits are targeted on this group.

                               BUSINESSES

    Businesses make purchases, as well. They also hire or fire workers. 
The effect on the business sector is crucial.
    There often is misunderstanding, however, about which federal 
policies are most effective in maintaining business purchases and 
employment when the economy weakens materially. The primary factor in 
such circumstances is not the cash that businesses have on hand; it is 
whether customers are spending money and buying their products.
    A business with ample cash to spend (whether through profits, 
savings, or government tax incentives) will not spend more, or refrain 
from laying off workers, if there is not sufficient demand for its 
products. Demand is a far more important factor than cash on hand in 
the employment and investment decisions of firms that see their 
responsibility as making profits for their shareholders. A firm that 
retains workers whom it does not need to produce the goods and services 
it can sell is essentially wasting its money and failing to fulfill its 
responsibility to its shareholders.
    As Goldman Sachs explained in an analysis last fall, ``companies 
don't spend money just because it's there to spend. To justify outlays 
for new projects, the expected returns have to exceed the costs, and 
that usually requires growth in demand strong enough to put pressure on 
existing resources.'' \3\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    \3\ GS Weekly, September 21, 2007.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    As a result, the single most effective way to maintain business 
spending and hiring is to maintain consumer demand. The tax rebate, 
unemployment insurance, and food stamp measures discussed above would 
all serve this goal.
    In contrast, business tax incentives tend to be less effective as 
stimulus, as CBO and other analysts have pointed out. A temporary 
investment incentive targeted to new investment (as distinguished from 
investments that have already been made) may provide some stimulus in 
situations where weakness in the economy is causing firms to postpone 
positive planned investments--if the incentive succeeds in inducing 
firms to accelerate their investment plans. But the stimulative effects 
of such incentives are likely to be considerably more modest than the 
effects of measures that put the same amount of money in the pockets of 
households that will spend it, because a substantial share of the 
investment spending subsidized through the tax incentives--even if 
limited to new investments--will be investment that would have been 
made anyway.
    This is borne out by the leading study that examines the effects of 
the ``bonus depreciation'' tax incentives that were enacted in 2002 and 
2003 to provide stimulus during the last recession. The study, by 
Federal Reserve economists, found that bonus depreciation had, at best, 
``only a very limited impact'' on investment spending. Similarly, as 
noted earlier, Moody's Economy.com estimates that bonus depreciation, 
the principal business tax cut in the new stimulus package, would 
generate only 27 cents in increased economic activity per dollar of 
cost.

                              GOVERNMENTS

    The actions of governments, as well, affect aggregate demand in the 
economy. Government actions that raise taxes or cut payments to 
beneficiaries or to firms or agencies that provide services reduce 
aggregate demand. When such actions are taken during an economic 
downturn, they make the downturn deeper.
    No federal policymaker would think of raising taxes now or paying 
for a stimulus package with contemporaneous tax increases or spending 
cuts. Yet we are headed for large budget cuts and tax increases at 
state and local levels. Those actions will be a drag on the economy. 
They will offset the positive effects of a significant portion of the 
federal stimulus package.
    Unlike the federal government, state governments (except Vermont) 
are required by their own laws or constitutions to balance their 
budgets every year, even during recessions. As a result, states cut 
programs and raise taxes in recessions. This decreases the amount of 
money that people have to spend or that the state spends, and thereby 
makes the downturn deeper.
    As of last week, 25 states were reporting budget deficits for 
fiscal year 2009, which starts July 1 in most states. This number is 
rising almost daily, as governors release their budgets and issue new 
budget estimates. We expect that within a few weeks, as more states 
issue new budget forecasts, at least 30 states will be facing deficits.
    Of the 25 states that have released new budget estimates and are 
projecting deficits, only 18 have issued specific deficit estimates to 
date. In these 18 states alone, the projected deficits total nearly $32 
billion. This figure will rise much higher as budget data become 
available for all states.
    This means that large state budget cuts and tax increases are in 
store. Two states have already enacted substantial tax increases to 
help close projected deficits. Governors and legislative leaders in a 
growing number of states are proposing hefty budget cuts, ranging from 
eliminating health care coverage for thousands of low-income children 
and elderly individuals to slashing funding for education, child care, 
and other basic services. When recession hits, health care, education, 
and aid to local governments are typically the three principal parts of 
state budgets that absorb the bulk of the cuts. In the last downturn, 
for example, state Medicaid cuts led to the loss of health care 
coverage for up to 1 million low-income people.
    Moreover, an unusual circumstance is making the current fiscal 
situation even more troublesome for many states. Many local governments 
are facing falling property tax revenues because of declining home 
values and are turning to their state governments for help, so that 
they do not have to institute overly severe cutbacks in basic services 
like schools, police, and firefighting. This is intensifying the 
pressure on state budgets.
    This strongly suggests that the federal government should provide 
some fiscal relief to states, whether in the current stimulus package 
or through another vehicle, as it did in the last recession. Lessening 
the degree to which states institute contractionary budget cuts and tax 
increases should be an important part of the federal response to the 
deterioration in the economy.
    Unfortunately, the current stimulus package would actually make 
this problem worse. The bonus depreciation tax provision it contains 
will cause some 30 states to lose $4 billion in tax revenue, due to 
linkages between federal and state tax codes that the majority of 
states have adopted to promote simplicity. This will compel states to 
institute bigger increases in other state taxes or steeper budget cuts, 
which is a harmful outcome from a stimulus standpoint.
    Two arguments are sometimes heard against fiscal relief. One is 
that some states are not in economic or fiscal difficulty. CBO has 
observed that fiscal relief which lessens the severity of state budget 
cuts or tax increases is stimulative, but fiscal relief provided to 
states not facing deficits is not.
    This concern can be addressed by targeting relief on states facing 
economic and fiscal difficulty. That can be done by using such measures 
as data on state-by-state changes in employment, food stamp caseload, 
and foreclosures. These data can be used to develop mechanisms that 
target relief on states whose economies (and budgets) are in trouble.
    A second question is whether, if the federal government provides 
aid to states in a recession, this creates a ``moral hazard,'' in which 
states then respond during periods of solid economic growth by 
overspending, cutting taxes too much, or failing to build up ``rainy 
day'' funds and thereby exacerbating the fiscal problems they face in 
the next downturn because they are counting on the federal government 
to bail them out. The evidence strongly indicates that modest amounts 
of federal fiscal relief during recessions do not have this effect.
    The federal government provided $20 billion fiscal relief in the 
last downturn. The data show that states have not overspent or slashed 
taxes since then in the expectation they would be bailed out during 
future downturns. On average, state expenditures as a share of the 
economy are lower now than they were in state fiscal year 2001, while 
state taxes as a share of the economy are at about the same level. In 
addition, once the recession ended, states built up substantial ``rainy 
day'' reserve funds to draw upon in the next downturn; at the end of 
2006, those reserves were actually a little larger, as a share of 
annual state expenditures, than before the recession at the start of 
this decade. In short, the provision of fiscal relief in the last 
downturn was not followed by irresponsible actions on the states' part.
    Although states built up substantial revenues (or rainy-day funds) 
before both the last recession and the impending one, recessions have 
such large effects on state budgets that they wipe out reserves and 
produce sizeable shortfalls. States began this decade with reserves 
equaling 10.4 percent of annual expenditures, a very substantial 
amount. Yet those reserves closed only about one-quarter of the state 
budget gaps that opened up through state fiscal year 2003.
    Moreover, a recession now could have especially large effects on 
state and local revenues because of the effects of declining home 
values in causing property tax revenues to erode. In contrast, home 
values and property tax revenues held up during the last recession.
    To be sure, it is quite possible that federal fiscal relief could 
create a ``moral hazard'' problem if it filled most or all of the state 
budget gaps that emerged during a recession. Relief of that magnitude, 
however, is not what anyone is talking about. The $20 billion in 
federal fiscal relief provided in 2003 closed only about 10 percent of 
the state budget shortfalls that emerged when the economy was weak in 
the early years of this decade. Today, the governors, on a bipartisan 
basis, are seeking a quite modest level of relief--$12 billion.
     moving beyond ideology and focusing on stimulating the economy
    The task now is to focus laser-like on what would, and would not, 
be effective stimulus. Consideration of what will be good for the 
economy over the long term remains important. But that is a separate 
discussion--and should involve a separate set of decisions--from what 
is needed to provide effective stimulus now.
    This means that certain nostrums need to be set to the side. For 
example, some people assume that tax cuts are inherently more 
stimulative than spending measures, but that assumption does not bear 
up well under scrutiny. As an array of distinguished economists (whose 
ranks include Nobel laureate Joseph Stiglitz, now-CBO director Peter 
Orszag, and Federal Reserve economists) have noted in the past, some 
spending measures and tax cuts can provide effective short-term 
stimulus, while other spending measures and tax cuts are ineffective as 
stimulus. Each measure needs to be evaluated on its own merits as 
stimulus. Simply labeling an option as ``spending'' or ``tax'' tells 
little.
    The current process of developing a stimulus package is off to a 
promising start. It is my hope that in short order, an effective 
package will be enacted that both builds--and improves--upon the 
bipartisan package unveiled last week.

    Chairman Spratt. Now, Brian Wesbury, who has a slightly 
different slant on the current economic situation and on the 
package.
    You are there on the panel to provide this diversity. We 
appreciate your coming. We are looking forward to your 
comments.

   STATEMENT OF BRIAN WESBURY, CHIEF ECONOMIST, FIRST TRUST 
                         ADVISORS, L.P.

    Mr. Wesbury. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and thank you for 
offering to put my testimony in the record in full. I will 
summarize it here today.
    You know, I am from the Midwest, the Chicago area. I work 
in the private sector, and so I am outnumbered here in many 
ways on this panel, and I am also outnumbered in my view on the 
economy.
    I think the economy is in much better shape than most 
people believe. You know, if you go back about 6 months when 
this problem began, many people feared that GDP, for example, 
in the third quarter would grow at 2 percent or less. The 
actual number came in at 4.9 percent, a literal boom in the 
third quarter. They said that, well, that is backward-looking 
now, so we are going to look at the fourth quarter. We will 
probably get zero-percent growth in the fourth quarter. We 
actually ended up--we don't have the data yet, we will get it 
tomorrow--but our estimate with all the data we have so far is 
1\1/2\ percent growth. So far, also, if you look at data that 
leaps us into the first quarter, we are projecting 3 percent 
growth in the first quarter for GDP as well.
    Last week, initial unemployment claims came out. They had 
been rising in late November and early December, but now they 
have plummeted back to 301,000. This is an extremely low level. 
Never in the past have we had a recession with initial 
unemployment claims at this level. And today, durable goods 
orders for December were released, up 5.2 percent in the month 
of December. If you exclude transportation, they were up 2.6 
percent. The fourth quarter's business investment numbers now 
show a 5.9 percent increase in business investment versus 6.1 
in the third quarter. No change.
    Now, I know I have thrown a lot of data at you, but I have 
never seen the level of pessimism that currently exists on the 
economy with virtually no evidence from the macroeconomic data 
to back it up. And therefore I think there is a large 
overreaction taking place today, that is potentially dangerous 
in the long run, to perceive the problems in the economy.
    One last point on this. The housing market, which does have 
a great deal of problems today, is only 4\1/2\ percent of GDP. 
The export sector of the U.S. economy is 12 percent of GDP. 
Housing is clearly declining, but exports are booming today, up 
14 percent from a year ago. And to strengthen that larger 
sector of the economy, the export sector, is actually 
overwhelming weakness in the housing sector, and that is why 
GDP continues to grow and initial unemployment claims remain 
very low.
    Now, having said that, I obviously don't forecast a 
recession, but clearly there is always a risk. Mrs. Rivlin said 
today that, clearly, economists have missed many recessions in 
the past, and I am going to tell you I am not a perfect 
forecaster. So let's take a look at what we have done so far. 
And I believe the biggest action, clearly, has been that the 
Federal Reserve has reduced interest rates 175 basis points. At 
3\1/2\ percent, the Federal funds' rate today is actually below 
the rate of inflation. In other words, we have a negative real 
interest rate. Never in the past have we had a recession when 
the Federal Reserve's--the Federal funds' rate is below the 
rate of inflation.
    So what I would suggest to you is that the Federal Reserve 
has already done enough to offset a recession, even if it were 
to occur. It takes about 6 or 9 months for Federal Reserve rate 
cuts to affect the economy. That means they started in 
September, we should see those impacts in March, April, May, 
and June before rebate checks can even get out. So my belief is 
that the economy will actually be accelerating before any 
stimulus package can actually go into effect.
    In addition, those rate cuts have caused some problems. We 
have inflationary pressures building in the economy. Last year, 
the consumer price index rose at its fastest rate in 17 years. 
The producer price index was up at its fastest rate since the 
early 1980s. The value of the dollar has plummeted. It is at 
its lowest rate in many, many years, and so more Federal 
Reserve rate cuts, which we also may get tomorrow, can actually 
put inflation into the system in a way we haven't seen in many 
decades.
    Let me just make three quick comments about the stimulus 
package from my point of view. It is kind of interesting to me 
that, yesterday--and I mean this euphemistically--we were 
worried about excess consumer spending, a lack of savings, too 
much borrowing, and a Federal budget deficit; and today, we 
seem to be running headlong into trying to get consumers to 
spend more, to borrow more, and to run the Federal budget 
deficit up. That is a very interesting thing to me, and I think 
that is confusing to many Americans.
    Number two, the impact of a stimulus is--it may help 
consumer spending for a month or two, but no manufacturer that 
I know of, no retailer that I know of, will build a new store 
or build a new manufacturing plant in order to accommodate some 
month-or-two stimulus in consumer spending.
    There will be no long-term impact on job creation from a 
rebate program. In addition, because we already have a budget 
deficit, if the Federal Government borrows money to write 
rebate checks, we will be crowding out private investment at 
the very time our financial institutions need that investment. 
And therefore I think a stimulus package could actually 
backfire by draining capital and investment capital from the 
system when we really need it.
    Finally, a stimulus package today that boosts the deficit, 
in my opinion, will make the permanence of the 2003 tax cuts 
less likely, and I think that is a negative thing for the 
markets in the long run. Our estimates show that the repeal of 
the 2003 tax cut, to go back to the pre-2003 tax rates, will 
boost the cost of capital for American corporations by 1 
percent, which will reduce the value of U.S. equities by 20 
percent. If you're worried about the stock market declining 
today, wait until you actually allow the cost of capital to 
rise by 1 percent for corporations. That is going to cause more 
problems.
    So I would suggest that rather than doing temporary things, 
that we do long-term things. I would suggest that we make 
permanent the 2003 tax cut. I think U.S. corporations today 
face an uphill battle when you compare their tax rates to the 
rest of the world. I would suggest we cut the corporate tax 
rate in the United States to allow it to be equal to tax rates, 
for example, in continental Europe, which are in the mid-20s, 
instead of 35 to 40 percent like we have here. I would also 
index the capital gains tax to inflation. I think, as inflation 
begins to rise, that will magnify capital gains tax rates, 
which will hurt investment at the very time we really need it.
    So, to summarize, my belief is that the economy is in much 
better shape than most people believe. I think the evidence 
shows that that is true today. There is no economic data on a 
broad base that shows the economy is falling apart, and I think 
an overreaction, not only by running up the deficit and forcing 
inflation higher, could actually cause more problems down the 
road than we have today.
    Thank you very much.
    [The prepared statement of Brian Wesbury follows:]

 Prepared Statement of Brian S. Wesbury, Chief Economist, First Trust 
                             Portfolios LP

    I would like to thank Chairman Spratt and the Ranking Member Ryan 
for the opportunity to come before this committee to discuss the 
economy and the extremely important subject of economic stimulus. I 
would also like to remind the committee that as I speak today, I am 
speaking for myself and not for my employer, First Trust Portfolios LP.
    I respectfully ask that my written testimony be included in the 
record in its entirety.
    As we all know, the economy and financial markets have been 
buffeted by turbulence in recent months. As far back as August 2007, 
credit markets began to price in significant financial market problems. 
Since then, defaults and delinquencies on mortgages (especially sub-
prime mortgages) have risen rapidly, home prices have fallen, the 
unemployment rate has moved higher, major U.S. financial institutions 
have taken large write-downs, and many of these companies have been 
forced to raise significant sums of capital, some of it from overseas.
    Obviously, we are here today to discuss what Congress and the 
Administration can or should do about all of this.
    But, in order to understand today's policy discussion, and its 
implications, I think it is important to put the current environment in 
the context of history. A series of five questions should put current 
economic issues and their policy implications in context.
    1) How did we get here?
    2) How bad is it?
    3) Are Fed rates cuts enough?
    4) Is more stimulus necessary?
    5) Is there anything else that would help?

                          HOW DID WE GET HERE?

    Twenty-five years ago, in the late 1970s and early 1980s, most 
intellectuals and many politicians were convinced that America's 
dominance in world economic matters had come to an end. The sun had set 
on the American Dream.
    Between 1969 and 1982, America was in recession roughly \1/3\ of 
the time--one out of every three years. At their peaks, both the 
unemployment rate and the inflation rate were above 10%, while the 
misery index--the combination of unemployment and inflation--rose to 
21.9% in May 1980. Oil and gasoline prices, adjusted for inflation were 
little different than they are today, even though consumers had much 
less purchasing power. In 1981, the 30-year mortgage rate rose to a 
peak of 18.5%, while the prime rate hit 20.5%. President Carter called 
it a ``malaise.''
    But in a surprise to the pessimists of twenty-five years ago, the 
US economy has boomed. Since 1982, the US economy has been in recession 
only 5% of the time. Over the past 20 years, inflation as measured by 
the consumer price index has averaged 3.1%, while the unemployment rate 
averaged 5.4%. The prime rate and 30-year mortgage rate have averaged 
6% in the past five years, while the federal funds rate has averaged 
3%.
    This long boom, with its non-inflationary, low interest rate, 
recession-free environment, encouraged an increased appetite for 
leverage and risk by consumers and creditors. While much of this risk 
was prudent, and was based on a correct belief that incomes would 
continue to rise, at its fringes, credit standards and personal 
responsibility frayed to levels that could not be sustained.
    This process accelerated between 2002 and 2004 when the Federal 
Reserve, in a battle against deflationary forces, drove interest rates 
down to levels not seen in almost 50 years. With the federal funds rate 
at 1%, the prime rate at 4%, and mortgage rates below 5%, exuberance 
gripped the housing market. Sub-prime loans, amounting to roughly $1 
trillion dollars were issued. This is ``ground zero'' for the current 
financial problems facing the US today.

                             HOW BAD IS IT?

    Despite significant dysfunction in the mortgage market, it is hard 
to imagine that there is any time in history when such rampant 
pessimism about the economy has existed with so little actual evidence 
to back it up.
    Some data has been weak. For example, retail sales fell 0.4% in 
December and fourth quarter real GDP appears to have grown at a subdued 
1.5% annual rate. It is also true that in the past six months 
manufacturing production has been flat, new orders for durable goods 
have fallen at a 0.8% annual rate and the unemployment rate has blipped 
up to 5.0%. Soft data for sure, but nowhere near the end of the world.
    It is most likely that this recent weakness is a payback for 
previous strength. Real GDP jumped 4.9% at an annual rate in the third 
quarter, while retail sales surged 1.1% in November.
    Just a year ago, most economic data looked much worse than it does 
today. Manufacturing production fell 1.1% during the six months ending 
February 2007, while new orders for durable goods fell 3.9% at an 
annual rate during the six months ending in November 2006. Real GDP 
grew just 0.6% in the first quarter of 2007 and retail sales fell in 
January and again in April. But the economy came back and roared, with 
real GDP averaging 4.4% growth between April and September 2007.
    A weak housing market helps explain recent softness in production 
and durable goods orders. But housing is now such a small share of GDP 
(4.5%) and it has fallen so much already, it is highly unlikely to 
drive the economy into recession all by itself.
    Exports are 12% of the economy, and are growing at a 13.6% rate. 
The boom in exports is overwhelming the loss from housing. This can be 
seen in the fact that initial claims for unemployment insurance have 
averaged just 314,750 in the past four weeks, and are currently 
301,000, a far cry from recession.
    Personal income is up 6.1% during the year ended in November, while 
small business income accelerated in October and November during the 
height of the credit crisis. In fact, after adjusting for inflation and 
then subtracting income taxes, and payments on rent, mortgages, car 
leases/loans, credit card interest, and property taxes, real personal 
income is up 3.9% during the year through September.
    Commercial paper issuance is rising again, as are mortgage 
applications, Libor spreads have returned to more normal levels, while 
commercial and industrial loans are up 29.7% at an annual rate in the 
past six months. In addition, firms and sectors of the economy that 
have experienced large declines in equity values, or large losses, are 
attracting capital from private and foreign sources. Presumably, these 
buyers and investors are well aware of the problems that exist, yet see 
great opportunity.
    In other words, not only is a recession unlikely, but it appears 
capital markets are already deep into a process that will lead to a 
full recovery of the financial system. When combined with rapid and 
large cuts in the federal funds rate, the economy is poised to grow 
rapidly for the remainder of 2008.

                       ARE FED RATE CUTS ENOUGH?

    The Federal Reserve has cut the federal funds rate from 5.25% to 
3.5% in the past five months. The most recent rate cut, of 75 basis 
points on January 22nd, was the largest single Fed rate reduction in a 
quarter of a century.
    The federal funds rate is now well below the trend rate of nominal 
GDP growth. In addition, with the consumer price index rising 4% during 
the 12 months ending in December, the real (or inflation-adjusted) 
federal funds rate is now negative. In other words, monetary policy is 
highly accommodative.
    This alone should be enough to hold off a recession. Every single 
recession since 1913 has been associated with overly tight monetary 
policy. As a result, the probability of a recession at the current time 
is much less than many fear.
    The argument that ``this time it is different'' is not overly 
compelling. Yes, it is true that many money center banks in the US have 
seen their capital eroded, and it is also true that credit markets have 
been dysfunctional.
    However, there are an infinite number of channels in which the 
money multiplier process can work. Even if some large financial 
institutions are impaired, other well-capitalized regional and 
community banks who did not participate in the sub-prime loan market 
are still lending. Private equity firms and foreign investors also have 
liquidity as do non-financial corporations in America with more than 
$1.1 trillion dollars in liquid assets.

                      IS MORE STIMULUS NECESSARY?

    Fears that current financial market problems could spread and 
create a Japanese-style market crash, credit crunch and economic 
downturn are remote. The Japanese central bank continued to hike rates 
in 1990, even after their stock market had fallen sharply. And it took 
three years before Japan's short-term interest rates fell back to even 
1988 levels. Japan also lifted tax rates during this time of extreme 
market uncertainty. The result was a deflationary recession.
    Today, in the US, monetary policy is nothing like that of Japan in 
the 1990s. In fact, the risk of an overly loose policy that creates 
inflation is much larger than a recession caused by excessively tight 
policy.
    Moreover, other fundamental drivers of economic growth are still 
solidly in place. Tax rates remain relatively low, and productivity is 
growing strongly. The entrepreneurial side of the US economy remains 
healthy.
    And because recent Fed rate cuts will take roughly six to nine 
months to affect the economy, by the time any rebate checks could be in 
the hands of consumers, the economy will already be accelerating.
    As a result, the stimulus plan, because it will increase the budget 
deficit in 2008, will engender rising expectations of future tax hikes. 
This concern will lead to a reduced willingness by US and foreign 
investors to invest in long-term projects which could create jobs and 
lift growth in the US.
    Congress should consider three other issues when making a final 
decision on whether to pass fiscal stimulus. First, it sends a mixed 
message. Yesterday, many analysts and politicians were worried about 
excessive consumer spending, a lack of saving, exploding debt levels, 
and federal budget deficits. Today, these arguments seem forgotten as 
we run full speed ahead with plans to encourage more borrowing, and 
consuming, while at the same time running up the budget deficit.
    Second, rebates will not change the long-term path of the US 
economy. Consumers make decisions about spending based on their long-
term income expectations, not on their current income. A rebate will 
not change long-term spending habits. Moreover, no retailer or 
manufacturer is likely to build another outlet or manufacturing 
facility based on a temporary consumer-oriented stimulus. In other 
words, temporary stimulus does not create new jobs or investment.
    Third, while I do not subscribe to the view that budget deficits 
increase interest rates, it is clear that government spending crowds 
out private investment. The money to send rebate checks in 2008 will 
need to be borrowed. Therefore, the very funds necessary to pay for 
this increase in consumer spending will reduce the availability of 
funds in other parts of the private sector for investment. This would 
be counterproductive at a time when markets are in turmoil and many 
financial institutions are in need of low cost capital.

                IS THERE ANYTHING ELSE THAT WOULD HELP?

    Yes. The expected sunset of the 2003 tax cut in 2011 is becoming a 
real impediment to long-term investors. As an active participant in the 
US financial markets, I already hear on a daily basis how the potential 
of higher tax rates is reducing the incentive to invest today.
    The stock market is especially at risk. If the 2003 tax cuts are 
allowed to expire, the real cost of capital for American corporations 
will rise by at least 1%. This, in turn, will result in a 20% drop in 
US equity valuations.
    A key determinant of long-term economic growth and rising asset 
values is stability in the value of money, the political environment 
and with future tax rates. If passing a stimulus package now increases 
the odds of tax hikes before 2011 because it lifts the deficit in 2008 
and 2009, this would act as an offset to any positive impact of a 
stimulus package.
    In addition, as we can see in record-high gold prices and a falling 
value of the dollar, inflationary pressures are already on the rise. As 
a result, it seems clear that recent interest rate cuts will be 
reversed at some future date.
    A reversal of recent accommodative monetary policy along with 
rising odds of tax hikes could hurt the economy at some point in the 
years ahead. In other words, policy actions to help the economy today 
could very well have a negative impact in the future.
    As a result, it is important that current policy be designed with 
long-term economic activity in mind. I propose three policy changes 
that would boost investment, innovation and productivity in the years 
ahead and help offset the virtually certain shift in monetary policy 
toward a more restrictive stance.
    1) Make permanent the Bush tax cuts of 2003.
    2) Cut the corporate tax rate to 25%.
    3) Index capital gains to inflation for taxation purposes.
    These three proposals will boost America's competitiveness, lift 
entrepreneurial activity and create a vibrant, long-term growth path 
that will be less inflationary, and more resilient.

    Chairman Spratt. Dr. Summers, would you respond to that 
point of view with respect to the status of the economy in 
particular? Are we selling the economy short? Is it actually in 
better shape than it seems to be?
    Mr. Summers. I think Mr. Wesbury does a very good job of 
stating the case against a stimulus package, but I think his 
judgments address what strikes me as being a small probability 
rather than the preponderance of evidence, for the reason that 
he essentially acknowledges when he recognizes that the kinds 
of statistics he cites are inevitably backwards-looking rather 
than forward-looking.
    The housing sector is in serious trouble. We got numbers 
yesterday suggesting that it was even worse than we supposed. 
Yes, housing construction is only 4 percent of GNP, but housing 
wealth is the largest asset for most American consumers, and 
its value affects their ability to spend. The availability--
what is happening in the housing market affects the ability of 
the financial system to provide credit. And it is those 
contractions in credit that those of us who are concerned about 
the economy see as most likely to slow and derail the economy.
    Insofar as GNP expands because we accumulate inventories, 
that is a basis for predicting slower GNP growth in the future, 
not more rapid GNP growth in the future. If one looks at what I 
think is relevant for policy, which is expected future 
inflation which we now--if I can put in a plug for something 
that we did in the 1990s in the Treasury, we now--because of 
the existence of inflation protection bonds, TIPS, are able to 
construct the market measure of inflation expectations, and 
what is striking is that inflation expectations have come down 
rather than risen. So I think it is a mistake to be overly 
distorted by the transient evidence that comes out of looking 
in a backward-looking way at the CPI.
    So I think what one wants to do is look at the experts who 
have updated their forecasts most recently, who now regard a 
recession as the preponderant probability. But above all, one 
wants to ask this question: Suppose that we should have done 
stimulus, and we didn't? Then we are taking, I believe, a real 
risk with respect to economic performance over several years, 
and we are taking a risk of allowing a situation in which the 
economy turns down, and that exacerbates the problems in the 
banking system, which causes the economy to turn down further. 
And we are running the risk of having the type of situation 
that plagued Japan for most of the 1990s.
    If, on the other hand, Mr. Wesbury is right and the alarm 
here is excessive, the Fed will stop easing sooner than it 
otherwise would have. We will avoid some of the distortions 
associated with low interest rates, and there will not be any 
very large loss.
    So, as Alice Rivlin recognized in her testimony, any 
judgment of this kind must involve a balancing of risk. And I 
would share her judgment that the risks of not acting, if the 
economy is turning down, are far greater than any risks of 
excessive action.
    Finally, Mr. Chairman, I would just note that, for reasons 
that I suspect members of the committee can imagine, I would 
entirely dissent from Mr. Wesbury's analysis regarding the 
consequences of making the tax cuts permanent and so forth, 
which, in my judgment, would be quite counterproductive for 
economic performance.
    Chairman Spratt. Dr. Summers, one more question.
    This is not, apparently, if we are faced with a recession, 
your garden variety, postwar, cyclical downturn. It has got 
structural origins; namely, the housing market, the subprime 
market, the mortgage market generally, and you just mentioned--
and so did Mr. Wesbury--that housing equity is a major source 
of wealth for American households.
    If the problem here is a decline in consumption--consumer 
demand--due to the fact that that wealth, source of wealth, is 
diminishing, can we counteract that with a countercyclical 
policy in the form of rebates to consumers, onetime rebates to 
consumers?
    Mr. Summers. Yes. We can respond to the fact that we are in 
a period where it is going to be very difficult for anybody to 
borrow against their houses by providing them with some cash to 
enable them to keep spending. We can respond to the fact that 
people are, to use the economic jargon, ``liquidity-
constrained'' by providing them with a certain amount of 
liquidity through the rebate, and the evidence is that most of 
that money will be spent. It is a different kind of recession 
in some respects, but it is the--it was sort of Keynes' central 
insight 60 years ago, that is still to the point today, that 
there is actually a free lunch in economics, and it comes from 
providing enough demand to avoid a recession. And in a 
situation where people don't spend and therefore people don't 
have jobs, and people don't have jobs and therefore they don't 
spend, can be avoided by priming the pump and generating some 
spending that allows some confidence to return and allows a 
higher level of employment and output while a process of 
financial repair is taking place. And that is the theory behind 
the stimulus, which again, I think, the balance of risks very 
much supports.
    Look, you all are in many ways closer to the front lines of 
the economy as you return to your districts than I. But as I 
look at the statistics and as I travel around, I don't detect 
an enormous number of labor shortages, bottlenecks, people 
working past capacity, and that the danger that we are going to 
overheat or overstimulate the economy certainly doesn't seem to 
me to be the paramount danger that we should be worried about 
at this time.
    Chairman Spratt. Thank you very much.
    Mr. Ryan.
    Mr. Ryan. Thank you, Chairman. I have so many questions. 
I'll try and limit them.
    One of the reasons why I wanted Mr. Wesbury to come testify 
is because I think it is always good to have a contrarian among 
our witnesses. That serves us as policymakers better.
    Also, Mr. Wesbury, you have an impressive forecasting 
record. Your livelihood depends on your ability to forecast. I 
think you won The Wall Street Journal Economic Forecasting 
Award in 2001 because you were one of the few economists to 
actually predict the recession in 2001. USA Today names you one 
of the top ten forecasters.
    We just heard from Dr. Summers sort of the demand side of 
it all. Give us just in a truncated answer, briefly, why you 
are not forecasting a recession this time, and how is that 
different than the one you forecasted in 2001?
    Mr. Wesbury. Sure. The most important input into my 
models--and the reason that I was able to forecast a recession 
in 2001--is monetary policy. Real interest rates in 2000 were 
very, very high. We had a 6\1/2\ percent Federal funds' rate 
with about a 1\1/2\ percent inflation rate. That means the real 
rate was well over 4 percent. Today, the Federal funds' rate is 
3\1/2\ percent. The inflation rate is 4 percent. And by the 
way, TIPS bonds have been a lousy predictor of inflation for 4 
or 5 years, but that is the big thing, and that is why I am 
predicting that we will not have a recession today.
    Mr. Ryan. Now, let me just go over the monetary policy for 
a moment, just because we have such esteemed people.
    Dr. Rivlin, I think--weren't you the Vice Chairman of the 
Fed in the late nineties?
    Ms. Rivlin. Yes, I was.
    Mr. Ryan. Yes. And obviously we know, Dr. Summers, your 
pedigree. Let's go into that for a second.
    Let me read from a column today by Robert Samuelson--hardly 
someone those of us on the right quote--the last two paragraphs 
of his op-ed in the Washington Post today.
    ``The Fed's first responsibility is to keep inflation at 
low levels because, without that, its other goals of maximum 
economic growth and low unemployment become impossible. We 
learned this lesson painfully in the 1960s and the 1970s. 
Political pressures, then, to avoid all recessions led the Fed 
to relax money and credit too often. The perverse results were 
higher inflation and more frequent and harsher recessions. 
Annual inflation peaked at 13.3 percent in 1979 and annual 
unemployment at 9.7 percent in 1982. * * * some economists 
think the Fed is already repeating its previous error, now 
prodded by market pressures and the specter of financial panic. 
If the market constantly demands to be stimulated by lower 
interest rates and easier credit and threatens to go into an 
uncontrollable tailspin if it isn't, then the Fed is in a 
treacherous position. Trying to make matters better now may 
make them much worse in a few years if higher inflation 
emerges. This danger is easily overlooked.''
    I just did 15 town hall meetings in Wisconsin, Secretary 
Summers, and there is a concern about the economy. But back 
home, there is also a concern about prices--the cost of living, 
health care costs, energy costs--in our area, particularly home 
heating costs, gas price costs. So the prices people especially 
living on fixed incomes, namely seniors, are experiencing are 
really eroding their standard of living and their income. And 
so my fear is are we trading a couple quarters of slow growth 
for a couple of years of inflation? Because if we bring 
inflation into this economy, it is going to take a long time to 
wrench it out of the system. It is going to be a painful 
stepping on the brakes that will occur from the Fed. And then 
all those people who are living on fixed incomes today, 
seniors--we have a whole bunch of baby boomers beginning to 
retire. Their standard of living is permanently diminished and 
eroded. Their ability to live on fixed income and maintain that 
standard of living is gone.
    So the question for those of you who have such good 
monetary policy experiences: Is the TIPS bond a relevant and 
timely predictor? Does the Federal Reserve now, in this era of 
instantaneous information exchanges, really have the ability to 
not only predict inflationary expectations but to make changes 
before they actually become embedded in our economy? And is 
there a risk here that we are going to overplay our hand and 
bring about inflation?
    Let's just go Dr. Summers, Dr. Rivlin--and Mr. Greenstein, 
do you want to comment? I don't know your monetary background--
and Mr. Wesbury.
    Mr. Summers. Mr. Ryan, I have been since long before I came 
to Washington a staunch supporter of an independent Federal 
Reserve, a major believer in the doctrine that inflation in all 
sorts of ways is harmful to the function of the economy. If I 
thought that a fiscal stimulus program would risk taking us 15 
percent of the way back to the 1960s, it would be something 
that I surely would not favor.
    I believe that as the Chairman indicated, we are looking at 
a very different structure than we have in the past. In the 
past, recessions have typically been caused when the Fed raised 
real interest rates in an effort to keep inflation under 
control. The situation we face today is quite different. The 
source of the instability is the asset bubble that took place 
and the strains that have developed in the financial system. 
And when there is no longer a demand for credit because the 
housing bubble is collapsing and people cannot be confident as 
to what is going to happen to assets, that is when interest 
rates fall, and that is why we have seen an abnormally low 
level of interest rates.
    We face a kind of price discipline from imports from China 
and other countries. It is unlike what we have seen in the 
past, for reasons that relate closely to the increase in 
equality we have seen. We face much less capacity of workers to 
bargain for higher wages than we have seen in the past. 
Whatever you think of--whatever one thinks about the health 
care system, it doesn't have its roots in anything to do with 
monetary policy.
    Indeed, I believe that failure to enact the stimulus 
program would in all likelihood place more of the burden of 
preventing financial collapse on monetary policy, would lead 
interest rates to be lower than they otherwise would be, would 
risk a recycling of the kind of experience we had before with 
extremely low interest rates----
    Mr. Ryan. Can I ask you----
    Mr. Summers [continuing]. Which would mean higher oil 
prices, a weaker dollar, higher commodity prices, and more risk 
of asset-priced bubbles in the future.
    Mr. Ryan. Is that observation based on sort of a 
psychological observation and, ``We are two-thirds of the way 
down the road on this, and if we pull back now, then that would 
occur''? Is that the premise of that observation?
    Mr. Summers. No. That observation was part of the argument 
I advanced in advocating a stimulus package 2 months ago before 
you were on the road. And, frankly, I would not have expected 
at the time that you would have moved as rapidly as you have. 
And so I have been very gratified by the response of the 
Congress.
    But it has been my view all along--I argued it in the 
Financial Times some time ago, and some similar arguments were 
made this morning by Alice Rivlin--that responding to the 
economy in a balanced way with both fiscal and monetary policy 
would provide for a much more healthy response than relying 
only on monetary policy, which would be likely to come with all 
the defamations that would come from an extreme monetary 
policy. And that the risk would be that if you don't have this 
fiscal stimulus, the Fed will have to cut even faster, and then 
those very low interest rates feed through in kinds of ways you 
spoke of, to commodity prices and all of that.
    And so I think if one is concerned about financial 
stability, concerned about the dollar, concerned about 
commodity prices, then one wants to have a balanced response to 
this problem with both fiscal and monetary policy rather than 
relying only on monetary policy.
    Mr. Ryan. Dr. Rivlin?
    Ms. Rivlin. I think the Fed is in a tough spot right now, 
and I suspect that they are weighing the inflation risk very 
carefully. They are always in a position of balancing, but the 
balance is especially difficult right now because we have had 
the upward pressure on inflation from energy prices and, 
recently, food and commodity prices. But I don't think that 
they will. In that discussion, one should weight the 
possibility of inflation taking off, as you said, very heavily. 
We have not seen that.
    I was at the Fed in the late 1990s when we were truly 
mystified by what was happening in the economy because it was 
growing so fast and because unemployment was so low, it got 
under 4 percent at some point, and all of the Fed's staff were 
running their models and saying, ``You got to be careful, you 
are going to have inflation, you ought to raise interest 
rates,'' and inflation did not happen.
    And we've also seen, in this more recent period, a big run-
up in oil prices that any economist would have predicted would 
pass through to consumer price indexes, and it has basically 
not happened. Now, I think that is for the reasons that Larry 
cited. We are a much more flexible economy than we used to be. 
We use less oil per GDP created. We are subject to a lot of 
downward pressures on inflation on both wages and prices from 
global competition. So we're just not in a position where 
inflation might suddenly take off, which was the worry in the 
1960s and 1970s; it is not now.
    I am not dismissing the inflation worry, but the other 
thing the Fed does have to worry about, if it overdoes the 
monetary stimulus, is another asset price bubble of whatever 
kind. They are certainly being blamed now in retrospect for 
having gotten interest rates down so low that it stimulated the 
housing bubble. They don't want to be in that position again.
    So I think the fiscal stimulus is, as I said in my 
testimony, partly insurance against the risk of recession and 
partly to take the burden off the Fed so they don't have to 
lower it as much as they otherwise would.
    Mr. Ryan. It seems the experience of the 1990s has sort of 
disproven the Phillips curve. I'm not going to get into asking 
you to comment on that, but----
    Ms. Rivlin. Thanks.
    Mr. Ryan. Because I think I know your answer. But on to the 
measurements we use to predict inflationary expectations--the 
Michigan consumer survey, TIPS bonds--in your opinion, are 
those accurate enough and do they give the Fed enough running 
time and enough of a fair warning to act accordingly to prevent 
those expectations from embedding themselves into the economy?
    Ms. Rivlin. I don't think we know much about how to predict 
inflation and inflation expectations. I am very glad that the 
Summers Treasury created the TIPS, but they are not, as Mr. 
Wesbury said, a very good predictor.
    Mr. Ryan. No offense, Bob. I just want to skip to Mr. 
Wesbury because I want to be judicious with my time, and I just 
have one quick Fannie-Freddie question I want to ask Dr. 
Summers.
    Mr. Wesbury. The reason I said TIPS have not proven to be a 
very good forecaster is 4 and 5 years ago they were saying we 
would have about 2 percent inflation. In fact, inflation has 
averaged over 3 percent.
    We don't have a lot of long-term data, but I just look at 
the last 4 or 5 years. If you would have bought a TIPS bond 4 
years ago, you would have done much better than a nominal 
Treasury bond because they were underestimating inflation by a 
large amount.
    I want to go back to something Dr. Summers says, and that 
is that suppose that we should have done stimulus and we 
didn't. This is always a serious question that you have to 
wrestle with. But one of the things that I would like to point 
out--and your reading of the Samuelson piece in I think it was 
The Washington Post today points this out--that if you go back 
to the 1970s, I believe we got into a situation where we were 
always--I call it the tyranny of the urgent. We were not 
looking down the road and providing long-term policy. We were 
cutting interest rates to help the economy one time, raising 
interest rates to fight inflation the next, doing stimulus 
packages, trying to manipulate the economy. And this always, I 
believe, leads to an unstable environment. And that is bad for 
business and bad for the economy.
    And then one last quick point. John Maynard Keynes believed 
that the economy was not stable on its own, that it had to have 
government put guardrails up and keep it on the path, otherwise 
it was going to drive into the ditch at any moment. And I don't 
believe that. I believe that the U.S. system and U.S. 
businesses and U.S. consumers are more rational and better 
decision-makers than John Maynard Keynes believed, if that is 
the way we want to characterize his thoughts, and that, in 
fact, government action, more often than not, in fact makes 
things worse.
    And that is one of the things that I would say today, is 
that one of the reasons we are where we are today is because we 
drove interest rates down to 1 percent between 2003 and 2004. 
In 2002 they were very low as well. And that led to a huge 
explosion in risk-taking and leverage in the market and 
subprime loans and lots of decisions by people based on an 
extremely low interest rate that was not real, was not 
realistic. And then when interest rates went back up, all of 
those decisions now look bad.
    And so here we are going to try to give a little, I call it 
hair of the dog; let's give more low interest rates to fix 
this. And I believe that can cause even more problems down the 
road.
    We see it in gold prices. Gold is at an all-time record 
high. Oil prices are back to where they were in the late 1970s, 
early 1980s. The value of the dollar has plummeted. We have 
even lost--the value of the dollar has fallen over 25 percent 
in the last 2 years against the Albanian lek. All right? The 
reason that is, it is not because of budget deficits. It is not 
because our economy is tanking. It is because we have printed 
too many dollars. And when you print too many dollars, just 
like if you have a bumper crop of corn, the corn price goes 
down, the value of the dollar goes down. If we have a bumper 
crop of dollars--and that is the fear that I have, is that an 
overreaction to a problem that will fix itself will create more 
problems down the road.
    Mr. Summers. There is a line of thought that holds that 
sometimes people smoke in bed and that if you just got rid of 
the fire department they would be more responsible and you 
wouldn't have fires. And that is the kind of thinking that I 
think we are being exposed to here.
    I want to be very clear. I believe that a course of action 
that would avoid reducing interest rates, because we didn't 
want to have bubbles, and avoid having fiscal stimulus, because 
we didn't want to stimulate the economy excessively and have 
inflation, that, frankly, that was the kind of thinking that 
made the Depression ``great.'' Obviously, our situation now is 
not parallel to the Depression. But the policy thinking in 1930 
and 1931, after you had a financial bubble burst and you had 
substantial problems in the banking system, was essentially of 
the same kind: ``gosh, we can't inflate. Gosh, we have to make 
sure that our currency doesn't lose its value. Gosh, we have to 
just let the purging take place.'' And the consequences were 
catastrophic. And I don't think that is a risk that we can 
prudently take.
    Frankly, I believe strongly that fiscal stimulus is a good 
idea. I understand the argument that it would be better not to 
have fiscal stimulus and to rely only on monetary policy. But 
the argument that Mr. Wesbury is making, that we should just 
rely on the natural restorative forces of the economy to work 
this situation through, I think really is a prescription for 
turning a serious situation into a critical situation.
    Mr. Wesbury. For the record, I do not want to get rid of 
the fire department.
    Mr. Ryan. This could go on and on and on. And I question, 
sort of, the characterization of the Samuelson point of view 
and others.
    I want to yield my time.
    I just want to get quick, Dr. Summers, Fannie and Freddie, 
should we be lifting the loan limit without any commensurate 
regulatory reform, more transparency, a stronger regulator? You 
were very vocal at Treasury about having a stronger regulator 
on the GSEs. Is it a good idea to raise their loan limits 
without any increase in transparency or regulatory 
accountability?
    Mr. Summers. I think what would be best would be to see the 
issues addressed simultaneously and together. I think there is 
a need--I think there is a critical need for reform where the 
GSEs are concerned.
    Mr. Ryan. Thank you.
    Chairman Spratt. Ms. DeLauro.
    Ms. DeLauro. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
    And I want to thank our panel this morning for their 
testimony.
    I just want to say, as a Member of this body, that I've 
been really quite pleased at the way, on a bipartisan basis, 
that this Congress and this administration have come together 
in trying to listen very carefully to the preponderance of 
economic information that says that we have long-term 
difficulties and what we need to do is to try to engage in both 
monetary and fiscal policy and that, in fact, a stimulus 
package that would be targeted, timely and temporary would be 
effective at this moment. We moved, we moved quickly, 
especially on the House side. And I am a strong supporter of 
this effort, though my own views on employment insurance and on 
food stamps and, Dr. Rivlin, even on infrastructure, I will put 
those aside for the moment because I don't want to see a delay. 
I want us to move, because I think that that is what we owe the 
American people.
    Two questions, if I can get both of them in. I am not going 
to go through what is in the package. Some have said that--it 
is argued that the rebates are too small to make a difference. 
At least three out of four have dealt in a different way with 
that effort.
    My question, one, is on the child tax credit, the $300 
child tax credit. And if you believe that the child tax credit 
represents an important component of a stimulus package, would 
permanently expanding the child tax credit so that families who 
need it the most, lower-middle-class working families, receive 
it and that would help the economy? And as part of that, your 
view on your support for refundable tax credit as part of 
broader economic policy for the future. Let me lay that one 
out.
    The second--and, Dr. Rivlin, you mentioned the 
infrastructure piece in terms of the short term and the lack of 
payout. With regard to infrastructure as national policy for 
the future, in terms of long-term rebuilding our economy--and I 
would love to get people's views as to what you think about 
that. And that is not the short-term stimulus piece, but long-
term.
    Let me leave it there. And, first, let me get your views on 
permanency on child tax credit and refundability. Dr. Summers?
    Mr. Summers. Congresswoman DeLauro, I believe the 
refundability component of the current stimulus is very 
valuable. I think it is an important milestone in tax policy 
that there has been agreement on a bipartisan basis on the 
principle that any important tax incentive should be made 
refundable. I think that is a very important step that I 
salute.
    I do not believe that, as part of a stimulus bill, anything 
should be made permanent----
    Ms. DeLauro. I am not talking about the stimulus bill.
    Mr. Summers [continuing]. In the absence of PAYGO, because 
that would violate the principle of timely, targeted and 
temporary.
    Ms. DeLauro. Right.
    Mr. Summers. Over time, as Congress addresses tax policy, 
recognizing the need for pay-fors, I would very much like to 
see the child credit that you mention be a part, on a long-term 
structural basis, of the tax system.
    I might add, because although you didn't raise it 
explicitly I think it is responsive to your concerns, that I 
would rather see the child tax cut be larger and the stimulus 
tax rebates be available only to those with incomes below a 
cap, such as $150,000, as is contained in the House proposal, 
than to see the cap removed and the size of the rebate reduced, 
as I understand is under discussion in the Senate.
    In the long run, with proper pay-fors, I think we do as a 
country need to invest much more in infrastructure. Look at 
Katrina, look at what happened in Minneapolis, look at the 
opportunities for maintenance.
    I would say that I am somewhat skeptical of the some of the 
proposals that emphasize innovative financing, because I don't 
think finding the capital is really the crucial issue. And some 
of the proposals that emphasize innovative financing I think 
are really backdoor routes to changing the way we do deficit 
accounting in ways that I would be uncomfortable with. But more 
paid-for infrastructure spending, yes, absolutely.
    Ms. DeLauro. Dr. Rivlin?
    Ms. Rivlin. I agree with all of that. I do think the 
refundable child tax credit should be an important part of 
permanent tax law, but don't do anything permanent in the 
stimulus package.
    I also agree on infrastructure. I think we have 
shortchanged our public capital over quite a long period, and 
there are statistics to back this up. We need better 
transportation. We need an investment in our school buildings. 
You can name a lot of things that we are shortchanging. We have 
done a lot of private capital and not nearly enough public 
capital over the last few years, and I hope that that changes.
    Ms. DeLauro. Mr. Greenstein?
    Mr. Greenstein. As you know, the current child tax credit 
has a partially refundable component, but families with 
children that have earnings below $11,750 a year do not qualify 
for it. And I think, if I understand your question correctly, 
what you are referring to is that in the stimulus package 
families will begin to qualify for something in that area at 
$3,000 of earnings as opposed to $11,750 of earnings. And I 
definitely think that that kind of a change is positive and 
would be desirable over the long run, but only, as Larry and 
Alice have said, separate legislation, fully paid for.
    Ms. DeLauro. That is what I am talking about.
    Mr. Greenstein. Having said that, when we ultimately do tax 
reform, if we do, I think it would probably be useful to look 
at whether a more fully refundable child tax credit and the 
current earned income tax credit ought to be integrated in some 
way so that we have one larger, well-designed credit that is 
both more ample--better work incentives, fewer marriage 
penalties--than sort of having two that somewhat unevenly fit 
together.
    Final comment. Larry mentioned that the Chairman's mark in 
the Senate reduces--it is a slight reduction, reduces the 
maximum size of the rebate and extends the rebate to families 
above the caps that the House has. I think if you look at the 
changes in the Chairman's mark in the Senate, it slowly lowers 
the rebate, and it puts the money in three places. One, it, as 
I mentioned, makes the rebates uniform for families above 
$3,000 a year, so that the working poor families don't get 
maybe half the rebate a family at $100,000 or $150,000 gets. 
That should improve the stimulative effect. Instead of only 
covering middle-income elderly, it also brings in low-income 
elderly. That probably also increases the stimulative effect. 
And it removes the cap at the top, and that clearly decreases 
the stimulative effect.
    But I just wanted to note that there are three changes. Two 
would increase the stimulative effect; one would reduce the 
stimulative effect.
    Mr. Wesbury. Congresswoman, this is not my area of 
expertise. I would second, however, one of the comments just 
made about tax reform in general. I think that our tax system, 
being as complex as it is, actually diminishes long-run 
investment in the United States. So to the extent that any of 
these rules can be written into the code in a much less complex 
way, I think we would benefit a great deal.
    Ms. DeLauro. Thank you.
    Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
    Chairman Spratt. Mr. Hensarling.
    Mr. Hensarling. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
    First, let me concur with my colleague from Connecticut. We 
do appear to be in a moment of rare bipartisanship. I think, 
listening to the comments of our colleagues, bipartisanship 
might be defined as very few of us like this legislation but 
almost all of us are going to vote for it.
    Dr. Summers, I have a question for you, and that is--I plan 
to support this legislation, not because I am convinced that it 
will necessarily have a stimulative effect on the economy. As I 
observe in the Fifth Congressional District of Texas, middle-
income families are having their paychecks squeezed by high gas 
prices, high energy prices, high health-care prices, and I 
always champion the cause of allowing hard-working families to 
keep more of what they earn.
    But if the theory is that roughly $100 billion of tax 
rebates, some to people who pay income taxes, some who don't, 
is going to promote consumer spending and thus boost our 
economy, why is the reverse not true?
    You have come out in your testimony against foreclosing the 
scheduled tax increases that are due to arise from the 
expiration of the 2001 and 2003 tax relief. Those automatic tax 
increases, combined with other tax increases that might be 
imposed--the Chairman of the Ways and Means Committee has 
proposed an AMT proposal--combined with the two, 90 percent of 
all Americans could see their taxes increased.
    So I'm just curious, if we sit here over the next 3 years 
and tax the American people to such an extent, why is that not 
going to contract the economy if $100 billion of spending now 
is somehow going to boost the economy?
    Mr. Summers. For two reasons, Congressman.
    First, most of the time, the economy is effectively--
resources are fully employed or relatively fully employed in 
the economy. And so the only way you increase the scale of the 
economy is to change the potential of the economy to produce. 
And simply increasing demand will simply lead to a higher rate 
of inflation.
    We now face the unusual circumstance that the economy faces 
in about 1 out of every 7 years historically, recently, where 
there will be significant unemployed resources and a 
significant shortfall in capacity and that, by increasing 
demand, we are able to increase use of resources.
    So, normally, stimulating demand is not availing. At the 
current moment, we are at the relatively rare moment when it 
is.
    Second, insofar as it is desirable to stimulate demand, as 
both Alice Rivlin and I and Bob emphasized, tax reductions have 
to be targeted. And the calculations that have been done with 
respect to the tax cuts that some propose to make permanent 3 
years from now is that the vast majority of the revenue goes to 
a rather small minority of the citizens who are the people who 
are already with the largest pools of liquid assets and who, 
therefore, are very unlikely to spend at any rapid rate out of 
any reductions and revenues that they are given.
    So it is both that demand-side stimulus on a permanent 
basis is not a very good idea, and if it was, repeal of the tax 
cuts would not be the right way to accomplish demand-side 
stimulus.
    Mr. Hensarling. Thank you.
    Let me move on since my time is limited.
    Mr. Wesbury, what do you believe would be the impact of our 
economy if we signal that these automatic tax increases would 
not take place on families and entrepreneurs?
    Mr. Wesbury. Let me just say that I operate in the 
financial markets. Our customers are financial advisors all 
over the country. And one of the biggest questions I get is, 
are tax rates going to go back up in 2011 or before, and what 
is the probability of that? That will affect the equity markets 
in a dramatic way.
    And let me point out that the 2001 recession and, in fact, 
every recession in the post-war period has been a business-
investment-led recession. Consumers really don't lead us into 
recession. In fact, consumer spending continued to grow at 
about a 3 percent real rate right through the 2001 recession. 
It was a massive decline in business investment that caused the 
recession of 2001. And so, if you really want to keep the 
economy out of recession, you ought to focus on business 
investment, not on demand or consumer demand. I think that is 
pretty clear from history.
    So I think allowing those tax cuts to expire increases the 
risk to investment, and it will reduce it today. And as a 
result, as we get closer, the uncertainty will rise, and I 
think that is harmful to investment.
    One last point. I will repeat it; I said it before. That 
tax cut in 2003, because of its cut in capital gains taxes and 
dividend tax rates, reduced the cost of capital to American 
corporations by about 1 percent--that is a significant 
reduction when you are looking at a cost of capital in the 5 to 
6 or 7 percent range--which boosts the underlying value of 
equities by about 20 percent. Allowing it to reverse will 
reverse that process.
    Mr. Hensarling. Thank you.
    Ms. Rivlin. Could I make a quick point in this connection?
    This discussion of what effect tax rate changes have on the 
economy can't be had in the abstract. You also have to look at 
the spending side. The effect of making the tax cuts permanent 
depends on what you do about permanent spending. And right now 
we have built-in spending that greatly exceeds the revenues, 
even if we don't keep the tax cut. That is the problem.
    Mr. Hensarling. Thank you.
    I see I am out of time. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
    Chairman Spratt. Mr. Edwards.
    Mr. Edwards. Dr. Summers, Dr. Rivlin, Dr. Greenstein, each 
of you have said you support a stimulus package. Each of you 
has said there are ways that you could personally improve it, 
or you would suggest improving it. And you have also said 
timeliness is key. So that raises, to me, the fundamental 
question of where we go from here.
    We have President Bush and Speaker Pelosi, who have agreed 
on a bipartisan stimulus package. The House will most likely 
pass that today. Even given your ideas and comments today that 
the package could be improved, given my concern that Congress 
better not let the perfect be the enemy of the good when it 
comes to stimulating this economy quickly, what deadline would 
you suggest to Congress so that if, for example, the Senate in 
its deliberations comes up with ideas that maybe the four of us 
would agree to but President Bush won't sign, what is the 
deadline by which Congress should have a stimulus package on 
the President's desk that he would agree to sign, in order to 
have the best chance of either preventing a recession or 
mitigating the impact of a possible recession?
    Dr. Summers, if you would begin.
    Dr. Summers. Two weeks from now.
    Mr. Edwards. Two weeks from now.
    Dr. Rivlin?
    Ms. Rivlin. Yesterday would be better, but 2 weeks from now 
would be fine.
    Mr. Edwards. All right.
    Dr. Greenstein, you mentioned the President's holiday 
recess. What specific date?
    Mr. Greenstein. I would generally concur with the 2 weeks 
from now, but I would like to have a caveat. And the caveat is 
that on the package as it is currently designed, waiting 
another couple of weeks probably doesn't make much difference 
for the following reason: Whether you enact the package before 
you go home for President's Day weekend or 2 weeks after that, 
the rebate checks still can't go out until the end of May. The 
problem of the rebate checks not being able to go out until 
then is not solved by a couple of weeks' difference in 
enactment. It has to do with IRS's ability to use the 2007 tax 
return data in order to develop the rebate amounts.
    And, of course, the particular reason, one of the key 
reasons why I am hoping both that the Senate can very quickly 
include unemployment insurance and food stamps and that that 
can be accepted hopefully and enacted quickly into law, is they 
are the two elements that can take effect much faster than the 
end of May, and that is of help.
    So when you say how fast do we have to act, on the one hand 
actually including those two elements, even if it took an extra 
week, would increase the immediacy of the effects than going a 
week earlier and not having those key pieces in it.
    Mr. Edwards. Thank you all for that answer.
    Would you each agree that if there is an apparent stalemate 
between the Senate and the House or between the House, Senate 
and the White House, and it looks as if this process could drag 
on for over a month, do you believe that would be harmful in 
our efforts to try to stop a recession from occurring?
    Dr. Summers?
    Mr. Summers. Yes.
    I would agree with the analytics behind what Bob said, but 
I would emphasize two points. One, the passage of the plan and 
the knowledge that the rebates are on the way is confidence-
injecting even before the rebates arrive.
    Second, my experience watching the Congress is that every 
day that things remain open is a day when something can come 
along that scrums things up and drives things toward deadlock. 
And, therefore, I think it is the better part of valor to be 
using 2 weeks from now, which I had calculated to roughly 
correspond to when I expected you would be recessing for 
President's Day, as a deadline.
    Mr. Edwards. Dr. Rivlin, would you like to comment?
    Ms. Rivlin. I agree with that, but I think there is an 
additional reason. The American people need confidence that 
their Government can do something. And this has been a really 
exciting thing for those of us who watch the U.S. Government to 
see, finally, finally, the Congress and the President seem to 
be, A, talking to each other and, B, negotiating a package that 
might pass. I would not jeopardize that for minor improvements, 
although all of the things that Bob Greenstein said are right.
    Mr. Edwards. Dr. Greenstein, you commented earlier. Would 
you care to add anything to that?
    Mr. Greenstein. Yes. To clarify, something that took a 
month or more to work out would really be a bad idea. I very 
much agree with Larry and Alice on that. I would try your best 
to get it done before the President's Day recess. I would have 
as my absolute drop-dead date the end of February. This should 
not go into March.
    Mr. Edwards. Thank you.
    Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
    Chairman Spratt. Mr. Conaway.
    Mr. Conaway. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
    I appreciate the witnesses being here today.
    This is an odd conversation to sit and listen to. I have 
heard this package described as taking a five-gallon bucket of 
water out of the deep end of your public swimming pool and 
wandering down to the shallow end and pouring it back in.
    I am hoping that, Alice, doing something, that the benefits 
of that aren't offset by us doing something wrong. We seem to 
have gotten to the need of this stimulus package rather quickly 
without a great deal of conversation as to whether we really do 
need it--more along the lines of Mr. Wesbury's comments.
    But I guess the backdrop of a $53 trillion of unfunded 
promises to each other that we will have to renegotiate at some 
point in time, and not reform them, but renegotiate them, that 
said, your comments that, Mr. Summers, you said we have a very 
inadequate personal savings rate, Federal savings rate; that 
living within our means does not seem to be something we do 
well at the Federal Government level, at the family level; that 
the asset bubble that seems to be the bogeyman in all of this, 
that we are turning back to the asset bubble creation model of 
easy credit and greater spending to get ourselves out of what I 
guess the preponderance of economists would say is a, quote/
unquote, ``recession,'' it just strikes me as particularly odd 
that we are at this juncture. And we are. And like the rest of 
my lemming friends, I am going to go across the street in a 
little while and vote for this package and hope that it is not 
too bad in that regard.
    I would like to have a head nod from each of the three that 
like the permanency of the child rebate, permanent food stamp 
increases, that you would nod your head that that should not be 
a part of this as well. Because raising food stamps for 20 
percent or whatever it would be for 3 months or 4 months and 
then cutting those rates back to what they are right now I 
think would be politically difficult for most of us to do that.
    Mr. Summers, you made a comment unrelated to this, that the 
tax rates that are currently in effect, should they go up, that 
the bulk of that revenue would go to the highest or the richest 
in our economy. It is just a difference of opinion. It is 
already their money. The Federal Government doesn't own it. We 
take it away from them at the point of a gun with our tax laws. 
And so it is just a phraseology more than anything else.
    We also talk about fixing the State problems, Mr. 
Greenstein, by some transfer payment from the Federal 
Government to the States to help them avoid the fiscal medicine 
that is living within their means, balancing their budgets by 
them raising taxes or cutting expenditures. We transfer that 
wreck from the States in a very blunt, indelicate way to the 
Federal Government and the Federal taxpayer. And to the extent 
that it adds a buck to the deficit and long-term borrowings of 
this country, my seven grandkids and their grandchildren are 
pretty much loaded up as it is. And so it is just an odd 
conversation that we would have that we can somehow get 
ourselves out of what may or may not be a problem at all of 
these levels.
    I don't really have a question. I try not to make these 
kinds of rants. I would rather ask questions, because you guys 
know a lot more about this than I do. But it just is an odd 
conversation where, on the one hand, we castigate Americans for 
not saving more and yet turn right around and give them money 
that they are supposed to spend. If you go to every morning 
show, ``Today Show'' or ``Good Morning America,'' every one of 
those financial advisors that comes on tells that viewing 
public, ``Start saving your money. Cut expenses. We are going 
into a wreck, and the way to help yourself out of that is to 
make sure you have your own fiscal house in order.'' And yet we 
at the Federal level just glibly say--and human nature is 
probably correct--that the bulk of this money will get spent 
within a relatively short period of time. But we add to the 
idea that you really don't have to save, that that is not 
really important in this country, that your Federal Government 
will come whistling in at some point in time and fix your 
effort.
    So if you have a burning desire to say something, that is 
fine. Otherwise, I do appreciate your being here this morning 
and sharing your thoughts with us.
    Mr. Summers. I would say this, Congressman. I have a 25-
year history of being for increased savings and being for 
strong market-oriented policies, and so I haven't come easily 
to this judgment. I would just invite you to consider that if 
we have a recession and that recession becomes serious and 
families are strapped, you are going to see much less savings 
than you otherwise would; that if you have a recession and that 
recession becomes serious, the Federal fiscal position is going 
to be twice as large a deficit as anything that people are 
talking about today, and that that is going to compromise our 
efforts to address all of these long-run problems. And so I 
think of this as a regrettable necessity to contain the risk of 
recession, which I think would compromise all of the various 
values that you spoke about.
    Finally, I would just say that I understand your point, I 
think, about whose money it is and who pays the taxes. But as a 
factual matter as to what is going to impact spending and what 
is not, it is relevant to look at the propensity to consume of 
the people who will be affected by a given tax change. And if 
those people are people with very high incomes, whether it is 
their money or whether it is the Government's money, it doesn't 
really matter for this purpose. You are likely to be impacting 
people whose spending will be much less affected.
    And so that is why I come to the judgment that preventing a 
recession is an imperative.
    And, by the way, I suspect you, like me, are a major 
believer in the importance of open international markets. And I 
think that the prospects that the United States will maintain 
its commitment to open international markets, with all the 
benefits that they bring, will be substantially greater if we 
are able to avoid recession or we are able to mitigate the 
consequences of recession than if we suffer severe recession. 
So I come to the position I do from the perspective of wanting 
to have as well-functioning markets as we possibly can in our 
economy.
    Ms. Rivlin. Could I just add briefly to that? I share your 
feeling that this is an odd conversation. It is an odd 
conversation because we haven't addressed the long-run fiscal 
sustainability of the U.S. budget. If we had, then we would 
still be having a conversation about what to do in recession, 
about short-run policy, but it would be a much more comfortable 
conversation because we had fixed the basic problem.
    Mr. Greenstein. Could I just briefly add, since you 
mentioned--and I think this is a significant point, the food 
stamp question. If you had a temporary increase in food stamps, 
would they go down at the end of the period?
    Let me just say, I have been involved, I think, with almost 
every piece of food stamp legislation and food stamp reform 
since 1973 and ran the program for President Carter. And my 
center and I are looked to in both houses by Members on both 
sides of the aisle when we design food stamp legislation. And I 
said to Members in the last few days of both parties and in 
both houses that the principle that anything in a stimulus 
package be temporary and expire on schedule is critical.
    And for what it is worth, given my pledge and that of our 
center that we would oppose any effort at the end of the period 
to extend any temporary increase, everything should remain 
temporary, without getting too technical, there is also a way 
to lessen the cliff at the end of the period. There is a 
regularly scheduled October cost-of-living increase in food 
stamps. One could design a temporary increase now so that it 
takes effect in April or May, depending on the State, and 
operates in a way that you don't then have an additional COLA 
this October, and it actually would help with the overall 
design.
    Mr. Wesbury. And let me make one quick comment. I agree 
with you, Congressman, that it is a strange conversation, is 
the way I put it. Yesterday we were telling everybody to save, 
and we were worried about the Federal budget deficit. Today we 
are telling everybody to spend, and we are not worried about 
the Federal budget deficit. And I understand that this is 
temporary, but it nonetheless adds to debt, it takes from one 
pocket and gives to another. And to the extent that Federal 
Government spending crowds out private investment, it actually 
hurts the very investment that we need to help fix the 
financial problems that exist today.
    And I would point out that there is a tremendous amount of 
activity in the private sector right now to alleviate these 
problems. Warren Buffett is investing in financial institutions 
and insurance companies today. Wilbur Ross is buying one of the 
bond insurance companies and putting it on better capital 
footing. A triple-A rating is very important. Foreign sovereign 
funds are investing in our financial institutions, rebuilding 
their capital. There is $1.1 trillion in cash on corporate 
books that is coming back into the market to shore up the 
system. I believe the private sector will handle these problems 
and that we will not have a recession.
    And then I would offer the opposite question that Dr. 
Summers asked, and that is, what if we don't have a recession? 
And I don't believe we are anywhere near one. And yet we have 
now lowered interest rates, run up the budget deficit, 
encouraged people to spend in order to fix one that doesn't 
exist. I think it creates problems.
    One last quick point. The last 20-year average of the 
unemployment rate in the United States is 5.4 percent. Today 
our unemployment rate is 5 percent. If we were to extend 
unemployment benefits at this unemployment rate, it would be 
the absolute lowest unemployment rate by a long margin that we 
have ever done anything like that before. So we are setting a 
new bar for the extension of unemployment rate benefits, the 
extension of stimulus to the economy that has never been set 
before.
    We are now interfering with an economy that is literally at 
full employment today. And so I do find this conversation 
strange. We seem to have reduced our tolerance for pain to such 
an extremely low level that I don't know how we don't react to 
almost any pain in the economy in the years ahead. And I think 
that creates problems.
    Mr. Conaway. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
    Chairman Spratt. Mr. Cooper.
    Mr. Cooper. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
    And thank you to the outstanding witness panel.
    I would like to highlight Dr. Rivlin's testimony, 
particularly on page six when she said, ``I believe that the 
stimulus package should be paid for over a 5-year period. The 
PAYGO principle has never been more important and should be 
honored. Making exceptions can become a dangerous habit.''
    I could not agree more. And I would like to suggest that 
this is actually, although Dr. Rivlin has stated it in the 
strongest form, a principle I think that all the panelists can 
agree on. Because at least you are not against PAYGO, at least 
over a multi-year period.
    Dr. Greenstein noted that it would be a mistake to pay for 
stimulus within the same year. But there is a pregnant pause 
there. You wouldn't be against paying for it over a 5-year 
period, I presume.
    Mr. Greenstein. I would be very much in favor of that, but 
I wouldn't want to blow up the stimulus bill over it.
    Mr. Cooper. I am not talking about delaying the package. 
But I would like to suggest, Dr. Greenstein, that if you don't 
get all your wishes in this package, that you and your center 
work with Blue Dog Democrats to find a way to pay for, for 
example, food stamps or other things that might not be in this 
package, and pay for it over a multi-year period so that it 
would have a stimulative effect. And I am not talking about a 
delayed timetable. Perhaps we could get this next package out 
next month or something. But you shouldn't give up just if you 
are not included in today's vote.
    So I know you are not giving up; that is not your nature. 
But there are ways to ferret out low-priority Federal spending, 
to have pay-for plans over a multi-year period that do not 
worsen our long-term problems. And, like Dr. Rivlin, that is my 
central fear.
    And Dr. Summers has stated it very well, too. He said in 
his testimony on page four, ``Including offsets in a 5- or 10-
year window would magnify the impact of fiscal stimulus a 
little bit by reducing any adverse impact on capital costs 
because it would avoid any increases in the long-run debt 
levels.'' That is my central worry here. When you try to 
enforce a discipline on a body of 435 people, plus the other 
body, it is very difficult.
    And here we will have honored the PAYGO rule in the breach 
for the third time. As Dr. Summers pointed out, we had the AMT 
exception, we had the war cost exception, now we have the 
stimulus package exception. Pretty soon, people here will 
forget that we are supposed to do PAYGO at all. And that is 
deeply worrisome, because the Democratic majority fought for 
PAYGO very hard last year. We have honored it, but today we 
will be honoring it apparently in the breach.
    The central question, it seems to me, when you talk about 
longer-term issues, like whether we make the Bush tax cuts 
permanent, is the percent of GDP that we want our tax revenues 
to be. It is my understanding that while they dipped down to 
almost Eisenhower levels, about 15 or 16 percent of GDP for a 
while there, they are now back up at about 18-plus percent. And 
that has been, as I recall, a 40- or 50-year bipartisan 
consensus, that tax revenues as a percent of GDP would be at 
about that level.
    Am I mistaking this, that it would be a substantial change 
in policy if we were to take tax revenues up to 21, 22, 23 
percent of GDP? Wouldn't that be a marked departure from past 
practice? Dr. Rivlin?
    Ms. Rivlin. Yes, it would. We have had--I think the long-
term average has been about 18.5. And every time that revenues 
have gotten above 20 we have had a tax cut.
    But this comes back to a point I made earlier. We now have 
promises made under entitlement programs that are law that will 
take spending up to levels that we have not seen ever as a 
percent of GDP--25, 28, you name it--over time. And unless we 
rein in those spending levels, we open up a gap between 
revenues and spending that cannot be financed and that will 
damage our economy severely.
    Mr. Greenstein. Could I add to that? In those periods where 
revenues were, like in the latter part of the previous decade, 
in the 20 to 21 percent of GDP range, they did not cause some 
kind of serious damage to the economy.
    But the larger issue is the one that Alice just mentioned. 
If you look at the changes you would have to make to Social 
Security and Medicare to keep revenues over the long term at 
18.5 percent of GDP without running crushing deficits that 
would ultimately cripple the economy, you would be looking at 
changes in Social Security and Medicare that I don't believe 
any party or any administration could pass. We're going to have 
to make tough decisions on both the health-care side in 
particular and the revenue side.
    And I think if we do end up making a decision to keep 
revenues at 18.5 percent of GDP for the next 40 or 50 years, I 
think that would be a decision to run deficits that would have 
crushing long-term effects on economic growth because they 
would be so huge.
    Mr. Cooper. The sooner we make these decisions, the better.
    I see that my time has expired. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
    Chairman Spratt. Before you establish 18.5 percent as the 
normative level, keep in mind, during most of those years, the 
vast majority of those years, that 18.5 percent of revenues we 
were running a budget deficit also, so we weren't fully funding 
the Government with the revenue take.
    Mr. Becerra.
    Mr. Becerra. Mr. Chairman, thank you very much.
    And to our witnesses, thank you for your testimony.
    Let me begin by asking each of the panelists if they can 
give me a quick response to the following question. If the 
Senate were able to add temporary increases to unemployment 
benefits and food stamps without delaying enactment of a 
stimulus package--you went through that discussion of how soon 
you would have to see a stimulus package--would that be a good 
idea, and would you support that?
    Two quick questions. Would that be a good idea if you could 
do unemployment and food stamps without delaying the enactment 
of a stimulus package? And would you support that?
    Mr. Greenstein. Obviously, from my comments here, my 
answers would be yes and yes.
    Ms. Rivlin. Yes, I would.
    Mr. Summers. Yes.
    Mr. Wesbury. No.
    Mr. Becerra. I appreciate your quick response to that.
    Mr. Wesbury, let me ask you some questions. I agree with a 
lot of your analytical trajectory, but I also agree with some 
of what Secretary Summers was saying, that we can't always 
predict that trajectory that well. And so, much of this is a 
very academic discussion because we don't know what things will 
look like tomorrow, let alone 10 or 15 years from now. But we 
are concerned enough that we want to try to stabilize things.
    And I think every time I talk to folks who work within the 
markets, they always talk about how important stability is. 
Even if it is something you don't like, so long as you could 
predict it, at least you could take it into account in making 
your decision. So stability, predictability, I am told, very 
important.
    So Congress, if you are going to do something that we don't 
like, so as long as we know that we could predict that it is 
going to happen, we could factor it into the market's movement. 
Is that a pretty fair assessment of how the market operates, to 
some rough degree?
    Mr. Wesbury. Yes. And it pleases me that I can say yes to 
that. Congressman, you have hit on something I think that is 
real important. Let me kind of step back just a second.
    Mr. Becerra. But very briefly.
    Mr. Wesbury. I will do it very briefly.
    We live in a time of massive transformation toward an 
intellectually based technology, and the only time period in 
history that looks anything like this is the industrial 
revolution. And that is when we were moving from an agrarian, 
farm-based economy to a city, manufacturing-based economy. And 
people didn't like it. It was not fun to have to move from your 
farm and take your family and move it to the city. And a lot of 
that kind of transformation is happening today. We need fewer 
people in manufacturing because our productivity is booming and 
technology is changing.
    Mr. Becerra. I think a lot of people would agree with that 
particular assertion. The difficulty, I think, for a lot of 
folks is that we are not yet seeing this government, this 
economy, address the concerns of those who might not be winners 
in that transformation.
    Let me ask you a question. We have talked about the Bush 
tax cuts of 2001 and 2003. And a decision was made by the then-
Republican majority in this Congress and the President to make 
these tax cuts temporary.
    Mr. Ryan. Will the gentleman yield on that point?
    Mr. Becerra. If I may finish the question. If I have time, 
I certainly will yield.
    So the decision was made by Republicans in control of the 
Congress and the President in the White House to make the tax 
cuts temporary, knowing they would expire, there was a cliff.
    Mr. Wesbury. Right.
    Mr. Becerra. Was that good or bad for the markets to know 
that these were temporary? Was that predictable and stable?
    Mr. Wesbury. Right. Well, I can't speak for the markets, 
but let me put it this way. One of the reasons that was done 
was because of budget rules, so you have to fit in certain 
windows, and the market understands that. And so my argument at 
the time was, if you were in the third inning of a baseball 
game----
    Mr. Becerra. Well, but let me stop you for a second. In 
2003 we passed tax cuts that were set to expire well before 10 
years were to go through the budget window. There were some tax 
cuts that weren't set to take place until well beyond the 2003 
date or 2001 date when they were passed. So this wasn't solely 
a budgetary issue. There were some definitive actions taken, 
decisions made to let these tax cuts expire.
    And so, if predictability and stability are so important, I 
have a tough time with these tax cuts, understanding is it 
going to disrupt the markets because they are going to all of a 
sudden expire? Or did the markets, knowing that they were going 
to expire because that is the political decision that was made 
by the Republican majority and the White House, lead to that, 
and so therefore that drop-off, that change in the tax code was 
already factored into the markets?
    Mr. Wesbury. Congressman, I haven't done this work in a 
long time, but I did it at one point. And that is that, on 
average, in the past 50 years, the capital gains tax rate has 
changed every 3 years. We in the markets understand this. At 
the time of the passage of that tax cut I argued this, that if 
in the middle of a baseball game all of a sudden the umpire 
stopped the game and said, ``From now on, a homerun is worth 
three instead of just one,'' I believe the baseball players 
would start swinging for the fences, and their manager would 
let them. But they were also told that this would end in the 
seventh inning. When that came around, they would change their 
behavior and go back to the way that they were. As you come 
closer to that seventh inning,all of a sudden you begin to 
sense that it is coming, that change is coming. So as we get 
closer to 2011, more people start to worry about it, are they 
going to be extended or not? Also----
    Mr. Becerra. I think you gave me an answer.
    And I know, Mr. Chairman, my time is expired, so I will 
just conclude with this. I wish we had more time to get into 
this.
    I would use the analogy of a child more than a baseball 
player. You give a child candy during dinner and you tell the 
child you only get so much candy and for so much time, the 
child will enjoy getting that candy. When the date of 
expiration of being able to have candy at dinner is upon that 
child, the child is going to complain because you gave that 
child candy during dinner. And everyone wants to be able to 
continue eating candy. But you can't always have candy because 
it is not always the best thing for you.
    I get the sense that, from what you have said, that markets 
have, to some degree, factored in what the Republican majority 
in Congress, what the President did in 2001 and 2003, to have 
these things expire. So I doubt that there will be this massive 
disruption in the markets. I do agree, though, that you do 
begin to build in this confidence that those tax cuts will 
remain in place. The difficulty is there is a price for eating 
candy all the time.
    My final comment, if I can very quickly, is I have a 
problem, Mr. Wesbury, when you said a moment ago in your 
comments about the economy and how it is not moving necessarily 
as well as you would like but it is moving sportingly along, 
where you said the economy is literally at full employment 
today.
    For the 7.5 million Americans who are not employed, for the 
1.3 million Americans who have been unemployed for more than 26 
weeks, for the other, I believe, millions of Americans who are 
underemployed, meaning not full-time work, this is not full 
employment. And I really cringe when I hear people say that 5 
percent unemployment in a country of 300 million is literally 
full employment. And I would hope that economists would 
understand that that is why you get as bad a name as 
politicians, because you disregard what Main Street is 
suffering when you speak only from Wall Street's perspective.
    And I yield back, Mr. Chairman.
    Chairman Spratt. Dr. Summers.
    Mr. Summers. Congressman Becerra, I got lost in some of the 
analogies. When I take my kids to the ballgames, they eat too 
much, and they want to keep eating even after the ballgame is 
over.
    I think Mr. Greenstein set here an admirable example for us 
all. He is a passionate defender of more food stamps, and yet 
he made very clear that he would oppose extension here, and I 
think all of us--I think particularly egregiously the Bush 
administration--but I think, if we're honest, all of us have 
been known to be tempted by enacting for a temporary period our 
preferred programs in the hope and sometimes even in the 
expectations that they will be made permanent, and I think we 
would have better and more rational budgeting in this country 
if things that were intended to be permanent were labeled as 
permanent, advocated as permanent and scored as permanent, and, 
of things that were described as temporary, even the proponents 
were prepared to commit to argue that they would not extend. 
And I think the Bush tax cuts are a particularly strong example 
of that with the potential for instability of the kind you 
describe, but I think, in all honesty, Congressman, it would be 
probably a mistake to suppose that either party had a complete 
monopoly on virtue in this area.
    Ms. Rivlin. Could I make two quick points?
    Chairman Spratt. Sure.
    Ms. Rivlin. One is a question of what are we stabilizing. I 
don't think it is the financial market. It shouldn't be. It is 
the economy as it affects real people. That is the objective of 
the stimulus package, and secondly, why did the Congress make 
those tax cuts temporary? Because of the PAYGO principle and 
because of the realization that, in the long run we would have 
to face up to can we afford those tax cuts in the light of the 
spending promises we have made. So the Congress was trying to 
force itself to say we have got to rethink this when we get to 
that point, and I think you do.
    Chairman Spratt. Thank you.
    Mr. Garrett.
    Mr. Garrett. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
    With all the reference to childlike behavior, maybe it is 
an appropriate place--here we are in Congress--in light of how 
sometimes Congress is portrayed as spending other people's 
money in a childlike manner.
    Before I begin, let me refer to the Ranking Member. I think 
he wanted to make just a comment with regard to the rules and 
procedures as to why our tax cuts are----
    Mr. Ryan. Yeah, I am not interested in invoking another 
nonsecular analogy.
    Just for historical accuracy here, a number of us served on 
the Ways and Means Committee when these tax laws were written. 
These 2001/2003 tax cuts were never designed to be temporary. 
When they left the Ways and Means Committee, when they left the 
House, they were permanent. Then because of the Byrd rule, a 
rule in the Senate that applies only to the Senate, they were 
required to be temporary with the sunset. It was our intention, 
the Republicans' intention, to make them permanent, but we 
didn't have the 60 votes needed to do that. We had 55. Because 
we didn't have the votes to keep them permanent, they were made 
temporary.
    That was never our design, never an intention. It was a 
result of the fact that there were not enough--I am not trying 
to be partisan here--Democrats to make them permanent, and we 
wanted to have the tax relief because of the economic problems 
confronting us. Always designed to be permanent. But for the 
Byrd rule, they were not.
    Thank you. I yield.
    Mr. Garrett. And I have to say that, when it comes to any 
new spending program, whether you label it a temporary program 
or a permanent program, I cannot think in my time here, which 
is 5 years, of any program that has begun or--nor can I think 
of any program that I have been involved with during this 
period of time that existed prior to coming in here, even 
though they were labeled as temporary, that anyone really felt 
that they were temporary.
    I mean, the one that comes to mind right here--I serve also 
on the Financial Services Committee. We established a 2-year 
temporary program called TRIA to deal with a situation there as 
far as the insurance matter. We just extended it now basically 
for another 7 years on top of the 7 years, so our temporary 
program is now going to be on--will effectively be on the books 
for potentially 14 years, and no one guesses that after those 
14 years it is going to be the end. So, whenever we talk about 
temporary, we have a--it is a misnomer.
    Likewise, earlier in the testimony--I apologize. I had to 
step out--there was some reference to the PAYGO rules and what 
have you, and I think some of the answers address that in 
suggesting that we can--I will use the phrase ``kick that can 
down the road'' as far as dealing with it. I don't know whether 
that is the appropriate strategy. I mean, if you are going to 
have PAYGO rules apply--and I think they should when it comes 
to spending plans, but not necessarily with regard to tax 
plans--then you need to bite the bullet, if you will, and deal 
with them today because, just as with the temporary programs, 
you never get to the day when you actually end that program. 
Likewise, if you kick this ball down the road for 5 years, we 
are never going to get to that fifth year to actually address 
that PAYGO rule. So that is my first question, and I will leave 
it to you to answer it.
    Secondly, when I came in, there was the issue of 
consistency, and I think the Ranking Member was addressing this 
as well earlier on in the testimony. The benefit, I understand, 
as far as the stimulus package with regard to the rebates and 
what have you is to do one of three things: stimulate the 
economy so people will go out and buy things, stimulate the 
economy by putting it into banks, stimulate the economy by 
paying some of their bills off.
    Everyone that I have talked to in the financial service 
sector says that this is going to have a de minimis impact; 3 
or $600 in buying things is going to be de minimis. The paying 
off of the bills will be a one-shot infusion into the banks, so 
to speak, as you pay off your credit cards, but the banks are 
looking for that consistency as well because they know this is 
only going to happen in August, and after August, you have paid 
your bill, but you are not going to be able to do it again in 
September. They are not going to be able to change their 
lending practices to say that we are going to ease up on the 
credit market at this point, which is what we are looking for, 
as liquidity out there to get the investors off the sidelines 
and the like.
    So my question to you is: Does that really do what we are 
hoping it will do in those three factors--liquidity, easing up 
the credit market?
    And my final one is, maybe, a little bit off skew here, but 
I will look to your opinion on this. There is a whole other 
range that is over here as far as a problem, and that is in the 
financial service sector, and that is the so-called ``side bets 
on the side bets'' with regard to the subprime area. And you 
have the problems with ANBEC and BIA and others in the bonding 
areas that are insuring this, and I have heard up to $43 
trillion worth of side bets that can be effectively just thrown 
overboard with regard to the subprime market and how that may 
play into here, which all of this means what we do here is just 
going to have de minimis or no impact whatsoever on that.
    So I throw it out to all of you on those three points.
    Mr. Greenstein. Let me take a tackle of the first of your 
issues on the temporary question and then leave the others for 
other panelists.
    Mr. Garrett. Okay.
    Mr. Greenstein. Obviously, in areas like what we call the 
``tax extenders,'' they never seem to die. They are done on a 
1- or 2-year basis. They are always extended.
    Having said that, there really is a counterexample to what 
you have mentioned. If you look at the stimulus package that 
Congress enacted--the two stimulus packages that Congress 
enacted on a bipartisan basis in the last recession and the 
President signed, everything in them was temporary and ended. 
So, additional weeks of unemployment insurance benefits, we 
have done those in every recession for the last 40 or 50 years. 
In every recession they ended, and they ended after the last 
one.
    The bonus depreciation tax cut, which is also in your 
current stimulus package, we did that in 2002. Some of us were 
worried it would become a new extender and become a permanent 
tax cut. It didn't, it ended.
    And there was temporary fiscal relief for State 
governments, and a number of Members were concerned that that 
would go on forever, and it didn't. It expired on schedule.
    So, at least with regard to stimulus packages in 
recessions, Congress actually has a decent track record of 
having things that are temporary expire.
    On the other hand, once you get outside of stimulus 
packages in recessions, the record, as you indicated, is not so 
good.
    Mr. Garrett. Thank you.
    Chairman Spratt. Mr. Doggett. Oh.
    Mr. Garrett. They were going to answer to----
    Chairman Spratt. I beg your pardon. Go ahead.
    Ms. Rivlin. I agree with that, but let me take the PAYGO 
question.
    I was a veteran of the Clinton budget years. PAYGO made an 
enormous difference and made a great contribution to the fact 
that we were able to reach surplus on both sides. I have 
explained to President Clinton umpteen times ``that is a very 
good idea, sir, but we can't afford it,'' and it was also true 
of the so-called ``middle-class tax cut,'' which you may 
remember he campaigned on, but we never did. The way we 
contained budget deficits was sticking by the rules, and I 
think the rules have to apply to both sides.
    Mr. Summers. Congressman, I agree in spirit with your 
emphasis that an important part of the situation the national 
economy is confronting goes to the challenges in the financial 
markets and, in particular, the challenges in the financial 
markets associated with securitization and its relationship to 
the derivatives that you are referring to when you use the 
phrase ``side bets.'' And I will submit for the record a couple 
of columns I have written in the Financial Times that give 
recommendations with respect to some of these--some of these 
issues.
    I would emphasize that I think that is a consideration that 
militates in favor of something like the bill the House is 
likely to pass today because the risks of disruption and 
carnage in the sector that you refer to will be much greater if 
the economy weakens, because inevitably, if the economy 
weakens, there will be more people unable to pay debts, which 
will give rise to more of the problems that you are speaking 
of. And so acting to prevent the economy from weakening is, I 
believe, more important because of the financial difficulties 
that you cite.
    I also believe that, because of the financial difficulties 
that you cite, there is more than the usual uncertainty about 
the impact that monetary policy will have in stimulating the 
economy, and that makes a case for a balanced approach to 
stimulus that uses fiscal policy as well.
    Mr. Wesbury. Congressman, I would just add to that comment.
    We have heard about, today and in recent months, the 
history of Japan and about the Great Depression. We have talked 
about both of those today and the potential of these side bets, 
as you refer to them, side bets on side bets--and you are 
absolutely right--with the derivatives market to lead to 
something like that.
    My belief is that you only end up in situations like Japan 
or in the Great Depression when monetary policy is extremely 
tight. For example, in Japan, the stock market crash started in 
early 1990 and fell dramatically, but the Central Bank of Japan 
was still raising interest rates throughout 1990, and it took 
them 3 years to cut interest rates back to levels that existed 
before the crash.
    Our central bank today has cut interest rates immediately. 
In the Great Depression, the money supply fell by 25 percent. 
The Federal Reserve was raising interest rates in the late 
1920s. That is what caused the bank failures and the deflation 
of the 1930s.
    So the belief that somehow these derivatives products can 
spread to take down the economy, my belief is--is that that 
only happens in a time of very tight money, and we do not have 
that today; we have very loose monetary policy, and you can 
tell that in the fact that gold has almost quadrupled in the 
past 5 years, and the value of the dollar has fallen by about 
50 percent. Both of those indicate that monetary policy is 
loose today, not tight, which tells me that there is a very 
small likelihood that the credit market problems will spread to 
take down other areas of the economy outside of housing.
    Mr. Garrett. And weren't you also talking about a problem 
of fiat money, us printing too much money now?
    Mr. Wesbury. Well, we have a fiat monetary system in the 
United States, and we have printed too much money, and you can 
see that because the value of the dollar has fallen. The price 
of gold is up. The way I described it with the dollar is when 
you have a bumper crop of corn, the price of corn goes down. 
When you have a bumper crop of dollars, the value of the dollar 
goes down, and that is exactly why the dollar has fallen versus 
the euro. It has fallen versus the yen. It has fallen even 
versus the Albanian lek.
    Chairman Spratt. Mr. Doggett.
    Mr. Doggett. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and thank you for 
your testimony.
    Dr. Summers, at a time when the Bush administration was 
still whistling ``don't worry; be happy,'' you recognized the 
dangers associated with this economic downturn, and I think we 
are among the first people to get out in front and propose a 
specific solution. You reiterate that approach in your written 
testimony, and your stimulus was in the range of $50 to $75 
billion, and you say you think that is the appropriate 
magnitude in your written testimony this morning.
    I asked Chairman Bernanke, when he was here last week, how 
much stimulus was too much stimulus, and he suggested $150 
billion, was about the level of double-triple what you had 
recommended, and it was necessary to agree to that level to get 
bipartisan support for this.
    My question to you is pretty much the same. Suppose that, 
with so many good ideas and not so good ideas out there and so 
many groups that are eager to avoid PAYGO requirements to get 
in on this proposal, we quintriple or quadruple or triple what 
you have and head on up over $200 billion of borrowed stimulus. 
Will that be helpful, or should we be focusing more on the 
range of $50 to $150 billion?
    Mr. Summers. I have just reread my paragraph under question 
4. How large should a stimulus package be?
    I think the paragraph probably will not allay the concerns 
of those who think economists don't write very clearly, but I 
think, if you read it clearly, you will see that I am 
advocating--express at one point, given the deterioration in 
the economy that has taken place in recent months, a package 
with a total cost of 1 percent of GNP, which corresponds to 
about $140 billion, would run very little danger of overheating 
the economy on any plausible scenario. So I am comfortable in 
the 150 range.
    On current facts, I would be uncomfortable if we went far 
above that, because I think there would be the kind--I think, 
at that point, the risks that Mr. Wesbury describes if we are 
talking about a $250- or a $300-billion package would, I think, 
start to be quite--start to be quite significant.
    I would add a technical nuance that, if somebody wants me 
to, I can explain in detail, but I believe that, for the 
purpose of judging the stimulative impact of the package, it is 
probably better not to look at the first-year number, but to 
look at the 10-year cost of the program, because businesses, in 
calculating the value of the depreciation allowances, are very 
much aware that the extra depreciation allowances they are 
going to get in 2008 are going to be given back subsequently.
    So I believe that, for the purpose of analyzing the 
economic impact of the stimulus package, it is probably better 
to think of this as being a stimulus package in the $105-, 
$110-billion range than in the $140-, $150-billion range.
    Mr. Doggett. Let me ask you one other thing.
    Your work is appropriately focused, as, I think, ours must, 
on finding a bipartisan solution to this downturn, but isn't it 
important also to note that it did not have a bipartisan cause; 
that while the business cycle is real, this particular problem 
grew out of the notion that markets could solve any problem 
with reference to subprime housing loans, and had it not been 
for excesses, an attitude that there was no need for any 
regulation at all of overzealous lending and you could lend to 
anybody whether they had a good lending record or not--had it 
not been for those excesses, we wouldn't need any stimulus 
today, would we?
    Mr. Summers. Congressman, I think I may use somewhat 
different words----
    Mr. Doggett. I hope they are brief words because my time is 
running out.
    Mr. Summers [continuing]. Than you used.
    I think there certainly were important regulatory failures 
that have exacerbated the difficulties that we have faced.
    Mr. Doggett. I will settle for that. And let me ask you one 
other question.
    The idea is to get the most cost-effective stimulus. What 
do you think about taking the cap off and extending the tax 
rebate to the folks that drew $180,000 average bonus on Wall 
Street last year instead of focusing it on the people around 
the median income in our country at $49,000 a year? Should we 
extend the tax rebates and give it to the people that 
contributed to this failure and to anyone else, whether they 
contributed or not, regardless of how much money they earn?
    Mr. Summers. I thought Mr. Greenstein gave a precisely 
accurate answer when he noted that the Senate reduced the size 
of the rebate from $600 to $500 and did three things with it. 
One of those things was to remove the caps, and I think he 
regarded removing the caps as being contrary to the objective 
of providing stimulus because it wouldn't be spent, and I share 
his view. He also emphasized, as I had not previously, that the 
other changes which went in the direction of providing more 
rebates to children in certain circumstances were favorable for 
stimulus, and I agree precisely with what he said.
    Mr. Doggett. Just one last one to Dr. Rivlin.
    I believe you made this clear, but we have had a wide range 
of economists come and testify to this committee, ranging from 
Marty Feldstein to Dr. Peter Orszag, who was here last week. 
Every single one of them has said that you could have effective 
stimulus this year and still comply with the PAYGO rules over a 
5-year period. Indeed, Dr. Orszag said you could even have a 
greater stimulus effect by complying with PAYGO.
    Do you agree with that, and do you agree with that, Dr. 
Summers?
    Ms. Rivlin. I do agree with it.
    Mr. Summers. I do agree with that as long as complying with 
PAYGO didn't mean delay so that you didn't have the stimulus 
package, which I think it would. So I am comfortable on grounds 
of avoiding delay with the decision that Congress made. If the 
Congress had found a way to agree quickly on measures within 
PAYGO, then I believe stimulus would have been even more 
effective.
    Mr. Doggett. And I gather, by your nodding head, that you 
agree, too, Mr. Greenstein?
    Mr. Greenstein. I do, and--because it clearly is not 
politically possible to move quickly and pay for the stimulus 
package. What that does is underscore the absolute critical 
importance of the temporary nature. The long-term effects on 
deficits are very small if everything here is temporary. It 
will be very important to ensure everything is temporary, and, 
if the economy recovers, then everything expires on schedule.
    Mr. Doggett. Thank you.
    Chairman Spratt. Mr. Blumenauer.
    Mr. Blumenauer. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
    I actually have enjoyed sort of getting some of the back 
and forth here. I am a little troubled with the 
oversimplification that some are suggesting that, a few weeks 
ago, we were worried that people weren't saving enough money 
and borrowing too much, and now we are changing all those 
signals, saying that we want them to spend and borrow more.
    I think it is quite clear that we are talking about a long-
term, substantial policy change to strengthen investment and 
savings versus a short-term stimulus, and I would hope that 
people in Congress would be able to keep those two concepts in 
mind. They are not inconsistent at all. It is like driving to 
the store, but occasionally you have to turn right or turn left 
to get someplace that is straight ahead. And I, too, am 
prepared, I think, to support not quite as enthusiastically as 
I would if some of the provisions that--at least three of the 
four of you had talked about were in it. I would like it to be 
consistent with PAYGO in the shorter term rather than the 
longer term, and I would like to put it in the hands of people 
who need it more. I guess I am one of those people that is 
deeply troubled by the long-term economic picture.
    Dr. Summers, I think you referenced the fact that this 
cratering out is centered on people's homeownership that is 
going to have ripple effects in ways that we haven't seen, 
arguably, since the Depression in terms of the drop in home 
values, the impact that that has on individuals' behaviors, the 
actual credit access they get to, and problems that are going 
to be subjected to them, and State and local finance that goes 
beyond just 4 percent of the economy that is involved with home 
construction. I am deeply troubled by how this is going to 
unwind, which makes me, I guess, even more concerned about Mr. 
Doggett's regulatory framework and what is going to happen with 
the long-term investment and infrastructure in this country, 
and both of you referenced it is not really a short-term fix, 
but it speaks to long-term economic health.
    I would like you to help me think through a couple of 
aspects of that. We are going to watch the unwinding of a 
multibillion-dollar wind energy business because of the wind 
energy production tax credit, which Congress in all likelihood 
will extend before the end of the year, but people are not 
going to be betting hundreds of millions of dollars on 
investments right now for projects and equipment, so we are 
seeing--it has started to go down. All three times that this 
has expired in the past, the industry tanks.
    Also, we are looking for the first time in our history at a 
deficit in the Highway Trust Fund, which has no borrowing 
authority, which is going to result in a pretty dramatic 
scaling back of transportation investments, probably a 4-to-1 
ratio, because of the low spend-out rate. So Congress, in all 
likelihood, is going to act within the year on both of these 
areas, but not before there is some negative consequence for 
the economy.
    I am wondering if you think that these admittedly specific 
infrastructure items that are a little hard to quantify don't 
have some part of our decision-making in terms of either now or 
what is going to happen. We will be doing more for economic 
stimulus, I am convinced, before this Congress is out.
    How do I think about things like this that are going to 
start having a negative consequence, in some cases already are?
    Ms. Rivlin. I think you think about them as unfortunate and 
try to fix them, and they just speak to the general point that 
the Congress should be making decisions about big, important 
things like infrastructure on a much more--on a long-term 
basis. And it isn't just infrastructure, it is the entitlement 
programs. It is everything. You aren't at the moment thinking 
hard about what is the total stuff that we want to fund here, 
and how are we going to pay for it, and these are just a couple 
of examples.
    Mr. Blumenauer. But is this just part of the big averaging 
of the economy, that we shouldn't be worrying about pulling out 
a couple of things like this in the context of stimulating the 
economy?
    Ms. Rivlin. I don't know how big those two particular 
things are, but I wouldn't mix up this longer-run stability 
question, which is really important, with the short-run 
stimulus.
    Mr. Summers. Congressman, I share the concern in both 
areas, but I think an effort to combine it with the economic 
stimulus issue would--as legitimate as your issues are, I think 
they are by no means unique. And there will be many, many 
people with legitimate issues, and an effort to bundle them all 
into stimulus would, I think, make the prospect of agreement 
quickly very unlikely.
    I would just say on infrastructure that--and I am not by 
any means an expert on the infrastructure issue--that as 
important as I think it is, I think there is ample reason to 
believe that the Congress has not always in the past been as 
effective in choosing the infrastructure projects that will 
have the highest rate of return for the national economy 
relative to the projects that will respond to a variety of 
constituency interests as at least we economists would prefer. 
And I think the degree of enthusiasm that could be generated 
across a wide coalition for increased infrastructure investment 
would be substantially increased if there was a sense that 
there were mechanisms in place that would assure that the 
projects were going to be selected for maximum economic 
efficiency.
    Mr. Blumenauer. No quarrel there.
    And, Mr. Chairman, I have appreciated your courtesy in 
times past for our being able to start approaching some of the 
infrastructure discussion of what some of the longer-term 
solutions will be. I was just trying to get a sense of what 
short-term applications we need. I do appreciate your 
admonition, and I think that is in the ultimate scheme of 
things. I hope we can get there.
    Thank you, sir.
    Chairman Spratt. Mr. Etheridge.
    Mr. Etheridge. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and let me thank 
you, as others have, for this hearing and for our panelists, 
for your time and your generosity.
    Let me ask the first question, Dr. Summers, to you, because 
I want to try to be generous to my colleagues who are waiting 
for their time and try to stick within mine.
    I am very pleased, as are my colleagues, that we now have a 
bipartisan package, but we may disagree, and I happen to 
disagree with some of the pieces--we would like to see more. 
But the point I want to ask you is that, on one specific piece 
in it, I am hearing from my Governor and others are hearing 
from their Governors as relates to the piece, as relates to the 
bonus depreciation, how that affects some State government 
revenues, and my question to you would be--it was a top 
priority of some folks involved, but can you speak to this 
aspect in the package as well as any opportunities that it 
might happen to address as it moves along, if we can, to 
hopefully reduce the impact on the States as you have talked 
about earlier?
    Mr. Summers. As I understand it, Congressman Etheridge, the 
impact on States is strictly proportional to what happens to 
the Federal Government----
    Mr. Etheridge. Correct.
    Mr. Summers [continuing]. Because of Federal piggybacking.
    If the Congress were to adopt my suggestion that the bonus 
depreciation be applied only to incremental investment above 
some benchmark, that would plausibly reduce the cost on the 
order of two-thirds, and that would, therefore, reduce the 
burden on State governments on the order of two-thirds. And so 
I think the correct response, if that is seen as a serious 
problem, is to make the bonus depreciation provision an 
incremental provision which still gets all the benefit in terms 
of the investment decision that somebody is trying to work out 
a strategy with respect to.
    Now, many people will tell you that it is enormously 
complex to have incremental and so forth. I would only make two 
points. One, we do it successfully with respect to research and 
development, which is probably, if anything, harder to measure 
than physical investment; and second, I would suggest, as I 
have to others in the past on this issue, that a country that 
can put a man on the moon could probably figure out how to 
design an incremental investment incentive.
    Mr. Etheridge. I agree. Thank you.
    Dr. Rivlin, a quick question. You have just talked on 
infrastructure. Let me just add a point to that, and you may or 
may not want to comment on it, because I do think, on the whole 
issue, Congress needs to find a way to work not just 
individually, but with State governments across the range of 
all of those infrastructure needs from water, sewer, airports, 
transportation. And I happen to believe that schools are an 
important part of this infrastructure. If we truly believe that 
our future is tied to education, we have got places in this 
country where they can't meet it, and it seems to me we ought 
to find a way to put together a package and, maybe, a group of 
people that could sit down and work it across the timeline, to 
do a long-range look at it.
    I would be just interested in a very brief comment on that 
so I get one more question in.
    Ms. Rivlin. I would agree with that, and there are the 
right people--I don't think they are on this panel--to sit down 
and help you with that.
    Mr. Etheridge. I agree. Thank you, ma'am.
    Mr. Wesbury, let me ask you a question, if I may, in 
closing. I don't mean to skip you. I agree with what you said. 
My point gets back to something. I have been sitting here 
listening today as we talk about the economic downturn, and we 
are now in the potential of a recession. All of a sudden, I am 
scratching my head and remembering 2001, and that is where we 
got into the tax cuts where we have been arguing whether 
permanent, temporary. It doesn't make any difference. The long 
term means we did it based on we were having an economic 
downturn, and we had to help. Well, as I remember, that came 
about as a result of Enron and Global Crossing and people who 
had 401(k)s that became 201(k)s. I remember that. I had one. A 
lot of other people did. So we were helping the markets.
    And I guess my question to you is how different was that 
from the current economic downturn we are now facing? Because 
at that point, we reduced--the Fed reduced the discount rate, 
we reduced tax rates, and now we are talking about reducing it 
to help the middle- and lower-income people to put money back 
in.
    Tell me what the difference is between then and now.
    Mr. Wesbury. The biggest difference is that we really were 
in a recession then, and we aren't in a recession now.
    Mr. Etheridge. No, we weren't when we started. We just 
thought we were getting into it. Then we found out we were in 
one, and we kept priming the pump.
    Mr. Wesbury. It is always--there is always a delay of 
recognition. So, in other words, the National Bureau of 
Economic Research, who is the one that labels recessions, did 
not tell us until December of 2001 or January of 2002 that we 
actually were in a recession in 2001. In fact, most economists 
completely missed the recession of 2001. As late as June, when 
we were already in that recession, there were only 5 of us in 
The Wall Street Journal survey out of 55 economists that 
actually had a recession called.
    Mr. Etheridge. But my question is what is the difference 
between then and now, because we are trying to do the same 
thing now.
    Mr. Wesbury. Right.
    Mr. Etheridge. You are saying we aren't in one----
    Mr. Wesbury. Right.
    Mr. Etheridge [continuing]. And we aren't going to have 
one. 
    Mr. Wesbury. Yeah, I would--my models in 2000 said we were 
going to have a recession in 2001. We did. My models--these 
very same models that caused--that called that recession are 
saying we have about a 10 percent chance of recession right 
now. Today we have got durable goods orders. They were much 
better than expected. Initial unemployment claims are still 
low. All of the doom and gloom that we have been supposed to 
see is not showing up.
    And so I guess my point is--is that I--at least then we had 
a clear downturn and a whole bunch of data that led us to that 
point. This time we don't have a clear downturn. We have a lot 
of forecasts. We have a lot of fear.
    Mr. Etheridge. I expect, if you talked to all these folks 
who have lost their homes, people who have lost value in it----
    Mr. Wesbury. Of course.
    Mr. Etheridge [continuing]. And people losing their jobs, 
they are going to disagree with your model. I hope you are 
right. I really hope you are right. I pray that you are right, 
but if you are wrong, then I hope we are right in making some 
decisions that will soften that blow.
    Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I yield back.
    Chairman Spratt. Mr. Scott.
    Mr. Scott. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
    Let me follow up with that, Mr. Wesbury.
    When you say ``recession,'' are you using the normal 
definition of two consecutive quarters of negative growth?
    Mr. Wesbury. That is a rule of thumb that we have, but 
typically we look at industrial production, consumer spending 
and unemployment.
    Mr. Scott. That is the basic definition.
    Have there been any months recently where there has been, 
in fact, a negative growth?
    Mr. Wesbury. No.
    Mr. Scott. And so stringing three together with 
accumulative negative growth would be, in your view, unlikely?
    Mr. Wesbury. I believe so. My odds of recession right now 
are about 10 percent.
    Mr. Scott. Okay. Dr. Rivlin, you can have a lot of problems 
even though you are not technically in a recession. We have 
seen the median wage go down over the last--over the last 7 
years, anemic growth in the Dow and job growth and the record 
foreclosures. My question on foreclosures is if we--a lot of 
these people were caught up in the subprime loan debacle. If we 
were to have a fund where people could refinance in 6 or 7 
percent permanent loans, how would that fund be scored?
    Ms. Rivlin. How would it be scored?
    Mr. Scott. Would you have to score it if----
    Ms. Rivlin. I am not--I am not sure. You would have to call 
Peter Orszag and talk to him about it. I think it would depend 
on how you set it up. I don't think it would have major budget 
impact----
    Mr. Scott. Okay.
    Ms. Rivlin [continuing]. But I think it is a very good 
idea. It is a very hard thing to do because of the way the 
subprime loans have----
    Mr. Scott. But it is possible that it wouldn't cost that 
much on a Federal scoring basis.
    Ms. Rivlin. Yes, I think that is possible, but talk to the 
people who really know.
    Mr. Scott. As we were talking about the budget, Dr. 
Summers, you were Treasury Secretary when we built up this 
surplus. We have heard a lot about these earmarks. The way they 
work is if you have a $100 million appropriation, you have got 
an earmark saying out of that 100 million, spend a million 
dollars on XYZ project. If you eliminate the earmark, you still 
have the same funding.
    Is it true that if you eliminated--if you eliminated all of 
the earmarks, what effect would that have on the budget 
deficit?
    Mr. Summers. I think earmarks are an issue for the 
composition of spending. I think it would be a serious mistake 
to pretend that earmarks are in any way, shape or form the 
cause of the Federal deficit----
    Mr. Scott. Well, if you eliminate----
    Mr. Summers [continuing]. Or that eliminating earmarks 
would have a meaningful impact on the country's aggregate 
fiscal position.
    Mr. Scott. So eliminating the earmarks would have no effect 
on the budget because the money would be spent anyway.
    Mr. Summers. It would depend on whether the totals under 
which the earmarks came were adjusted or not, but the argument 
about earmarks should be an argument about efficiency of 
spending. It should not be an argument about the overall size 
of the deficit, and those who blame the deficit on earmarks are 
misstating the situation.
    Mr. Scott. Now, in terms of timely, targeted and temporary, 
we have rebates going up to families making $150,000. Over 40 
or $50,000, what is the stimulus effect of the rebates? Is it 
much less than those rebates that go to the lower half?
    Mr. Summers. I think, as best we can tell, that as income 
levels rise, the rate at which money will be spent declines, so 
I would expect that money that goes to those with under $50,000 
would tend to have a larger impact than money that went to 
those between 50 and 100, which would be greater than those 
between 100 or 150. Once you got above 150, I would be 
surprised if you were looking at much stimulative impact at 
all.
    Mr. Scott. Mr. Greenstein, you indicated that the 
accelerated depreciation would, for every dollar, cost 27 cents 
worth of economic impact. Is that what I understood?
    Mr. Greenstein. Not my estimate.
    Mr. Scott. Okay.
    Mr. Greenstein. This is an estimate by----
    Mr. Scott. Did that include the fact that you get some--get 
all the money back in the fullness of time?
    Mr. Greenstein. This is an estimate from Mark Zandi, who is 
the chief economist of Moody's Economy.com. I would need to 
look more at the precise methodology. I can get back to you 
with an answer.
    Mr. Scott. Okay. Now, Dr. Summers, you indicated that, if 
it had been targeted as incremental, you would get a much 
better bang for the buck, so that 27-cent figure would be 
significantly higher if you only had it available for the 
incremental cost. If it is not the incremental cost, you may be 
giving tax breaks for what people would be doing anyway, so 
that portion of it would have no stimulus effect at all; is 
that right?
    Mr. Summers. Correct.
    Mr. Scott. Dr. Rivlin, you indicated that construction 
projects were not as good stimulus because it took so long to 
get them going. If you limited the stimulus spending in the 
stimulus package to projects ready to go, would your opinion 
change? That is, if the Governor--if the Governor could commit 
to the fact that, if you give me this money, we will start 
laying cement; we have already bought it; we have already 
designed; it is ready to go; the only barrier is we can't 
afford the money; if you give us the money, we will start 
building the road immediately, would that change your mind?
    Ms. Rivlin. It would help, but it wouldn't change my mind 
about putting construction into this stimulus package, because 
it runs into all of the arguments about earmarks and other 
things. And the other problem with construction projects is 
they tend--people who are employed on construction projects 
tend to be relatively high-income. It is not as effective a 
stimulus as, say, putting money into food stamps, ever.
    Mr. Scott. Since the money, apparently, won't be getting 
out until the summer anyway, would a summer jobs program for 
low-income youth get the money into the economy effectively? It 
would be timely because it would be the summer. It would be 
temporary because they are summer jobs. And it is obviously 
targeted at people who pay--who would be spending their 
paychecks.
    Ms. Rivlin. I think that is a plausible thing to consider, 
but I wouldn't put it in this package.
    Mr. Scott. And that is because you don't want to change it 
because it may disrupt things; is that right?
    Ms. Rivlin. Yes. If you start adding things, there is no 
end to what you might add.
    Mr. Scott. Well, if it starts getting changed around, that 
would be a nice thing to add to a stimulus package.
    Mr. Summers. I would also be concerned that an actual 
summer temporary jobs program of the kind that would be 
implemented might, in fact, end up paying for a variety of jobs 
that State and local governments were going to create anyway 
rather than--I think it would take quite a bit of design to 
ensure that a program had truly incremental impact on the level 
of summer job creation, and that would be an aspect that I 
would worry about with--a separate issue that I would worry 
about with respect to that proposal.
    Mr. Scott. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
    Chairman Spratt. Ms. Kaptur.
    Ms. Kaptur. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and thank you all for 
giving us the benefit of your time this morning. You have been 
very, very generous.
    My two questions are: From where will the United States 
borrow the money to pay for this rebate program--I refuse to 
call it a ``stimulus''--and how many jobs will this rebate 
program create? Those are the two questions.
    While you are thinking about that, I wanted to ask, Mr. 
Wesbury, could you please tell me who the chief executive 
officer of First Trust Capital Partners is?
    Mr. Wesbury. First Trust Capital Partners is--the chief CEO 
is Jim Bowen.
    Ms. Kaptur. Jim Bowen.
    Mr. Wesbury. Yeah. I am not here, by the way, speaking on 
behalf of the firm. I am here speaking on my behalf.
    Ms. Kaptur. Okay. And do they invest any sovereign wealth 
funds?
    Mr. Wesbury. No.
    Ms. Kaptur. And their major business is not then with 
foreign investment----
    Mr. Wesbury. Absolutely not.
    Ms. Kaptur [continuing]. Filtering foreign investment into 
this country? Are private equity funds, to your knowledge, 
taxed at the same rate as regular corporations, both the 
executive officer's pay as well as the company itself?
    Mr. Wesbury. If the executive officer of a private equity 
fund receives a salary, it is at the same tax rate as you and 
I.
    Ms. Kaptur. And what about the corporation itself?
    Mr. Wesbury. The corporation income is taxed at the 
corporate tax rate, yes.
    Ms. Kaptur. All right.
    Mr. Wesbury. If there is carried interest, that is a 
different story.
    Ms. Kaptur. Thank you very much.
    I just wanted to state for the record what I said to 
Chairman Bernanke last week, and that is that I have served in 
Congress long enough to witness the dismantling of our 
traditional housing finance system post-World War II, our 
thrift system, our savings system, and we were told at the 
time--and I fought it--but we were told that if we moved into 
securitization and the global markets, that we would not risk 
any housing downturns; that, in fact, this was going to be all 
good, and we would never have to suffer what our people are now 
suffering with the rate of foreclosure and so forth. So 
something didn't work out in terms of safety and soundness. 
Either the regulatory process didn't work. Something happened 
to lead us to the point where we are today.
    Before you answer my two questions on where we will get the 
money to pay for this rebate, and how many jobs will be 
created, let me just state, for my district today in northern 
Ohio, what we need are living-wage jobs where wages rise with 
the rise in productivity that our people are putting forward. 
We are not getting that. In fact, people are finding their 
incomes shrinking in terms of real buying power, despite how 
hard they work. We need lower utility bills. We need lower gas 
prices. We need an energy-independent America.
    I ask myself, does this package lead us in that direction 
in any way? Our food banks need emergency food. They are 
running out, and they are oversubscribed, and the people are 
coming in the doors, and people are literally stretched to the 
edge. We need more LIHEAP payments. People cannot pay their 
utility bills in northern Ohio; not all, but growing numbers 
cannot pay. We need feet on the ground from HUD and from Fannie 
Mae and Freddie Mac to help our people work out, where we can, 
their mortgages. The rate of home foreclosure is exploding. I 
don't see anything in this package that does anything with 
those.
    Congressman Scott talked about a summer program. Our city 
government is having trouble paying its bills because of rising 
energy costs and even the costs of garbage trucks running down 
the road. The cost of the gasoline is so much more that our 
local governments don't have money for infrastructure to take 
care of local roads. We need extended unemployment benefits, 
and, frankly, the State of Ohio loses under the current 
proposal. Our Governor now--I don't know. They are going to 
have to--just trying to figure out anywhere from $100 million 
to $600 million that they don't have at the State level, that 
somehow the package causes Ohio to even have more trouble that 
it currently has.
    So my questions to you are: From where will we borrow the 
money to pay for this rebate, and how many jobs will it create?
    Mr. Summers. My estimate would be that it will create 
several hundred thousand jobs. That estimate is derived from an 
estimate of 1 percent of GNP--1 percent of GNP in stimulus, 
some multiplier attached to that 1 percent of GNP, and 
historical relationships between GNP and unemployment would 
suggest the likelihood that several hundred thousand jobs will 
be created or will be saved by the package.
    Ms. Kaptur. Dr. Summers, that is what they said to us about 
NAFTA, that if we passed NAFTA, we would get millions of jobs, 
and it has been a job drain all over this country. So I am a 
little--unless you can tell me where the jobs will be--if they 
are in infrastructure, food production, wherever they are, how 
do I know where they are?
    Mr. Summers. I think one could--I don't have the numbers at 
my disposal. One could construct estimates of an increase in 
GNP spurred by increases in consumption, and I think you would 
find that the jobs were widely dispersed with respect to the 
economy. I think, in light of the hour, I will resist the urge 
to debate NAFTA and its merits with you.
    As for the financing, the financing will come from the 
government issuing more debt. Historically that debt is 
purchased by a wide range of investors, some of whom live 
within the United States and some of whom are abroad.
    Ms. Kaptur. What percent, sir, of the current debt is 
purchased by foreign interests in the last fiscal year?
    Mr. Summers. It sounds like you know that number. 
Precisely----
    Ms. Kaptur. Probably 80 percent.
    Mr. Summers. You should provide it to us.
    Ms. Kaptur. Eighty percent by foreign interests.
    Would anyone else like to comment on where the money will 
be borrowed from?
    Ms. Rivlin. No. As Professor Summers said, it will be 
borrowed from the same sources that the U.S. Government always 
borrows from when it sells Treasury securities.
    The one thing I would stress in the answer to how many 
jobs, it is not job creation we are after here. It is saving 
jobs that would otherwise disappear on balance. It won't be 
necessarily the same jobs.
    Mr. Wesbury. And I agree that it will be borrowed in the 
Treasury market. The buyers will be probably the same ratio as 
typically are that enter into those transactions with the 
Federal Government.
    Ms. Kaptur. Mr. Wesbury, from what you know of the markets, 
which countries are likely to purchase those bonds if you look 
at last year as the trend?
    Mr. Wesbury. You know, you probably know that list pretty 
well.
    Ms. Kaptur. It is China or----
    Mr. Wesbury. It is clearly China and Singapore and Japan 
and OPEC nations, which have a big surplus with us because of 
oil.
    Ms. Kaptur. The oil-producing countries.
    Mr. Wesbury. Sure. Yeah. And we have a global financial 
system. We buy their debt, by the way, as well. There is 
investment going both ways, and I believe, by the way, that 
benefits the world.
    But let me address the jobs issue. I do not believe the 
stimulus package will create any new jobs. From a manufacturing 
point of view or a retailer's point of view, this is a 
temporary stimulus. It is designed to do that. Why would I 
build a new store or expand my manufacturing capabilities to 
meet demand that will be very short-term in nature? I just 
won't do it. And because we take the money from somewhere 
else--that is every dollar we borrow to give to--to rebate is a 
dollar less in the hands of an investor that could have 
invested in the United States, and today I believe we need 
investment, especially with the losses in our financial 
institutions, and any crimping of those dollars or capital 
available for investment actually, I believe, does the opposite 
of what we want it to do today.
    Ms. Kaptur. Mr. Chairman, would you indulge me for one 
final question?
    I wanted to ask Mr. Greenstein: You pointed out that food 
stamps and unemployment insurance are the most effective 
stimulus available, which is compelling, but it seems that 
there are more compelling reasons to provide help to low-income 
people in a recession.
    Can you talk about the hardships that poor families might 
be facing during a recession and how food stamps and 
unemployment insurance could help them?
    Mr. Greenstein. Well, food stamps and unemployment 
insurance obviously help people's bottom lines. The issues are 
not exactly the same.
    In the case of food stamps, we are talking about people 
with very low incomes. In the case of unemployment insurance, 
some of the people have low incomes. For some of the people, 
there is still a second earner in the family who is still 
employed, and they may not be in poverty. They may still be at 
some moderate income level. But from a stimulus standpoint, if 
you lose your job, and you get unemployment benefits, and they 
run out before you can find a new job, then there may be a 
significant reduction in consumption, and that is what we are 
trying to avoid in the stimulus package.
    We are trying to keep consumption up, because when 
consumption falls, then the businesses that sell goods and 
services don't need as many workers because they can't sell as 
many products, so they lay some of their workers off, and then 
those people consume less, and you get the spiral.
    So I think Professor Summers mentioned this earlier in the 
hearing. In essence, what you are trying to do in the stimulus 
package is to prevent that kind of a downward spiral; keep 
consumer purchasing up so businesses can still sell their 
products, they don't have to lay off workers, and you don't get 
this downward spiral, and obviously, we get a double benefit.
    We get from a policy standpoint, in my view, given my own 
views, a double benefit here that the types of measures that 
are most effective dollar for dollar in keeping consumption up 
and therefore stimulating the economy are those that also 
target on the people who are in the most trouble, for the 
precise reason that, if you are in the most trouble and you 
have trouble making your bills, you get an additional dollar. 
Whether it is an unemployment insurance benefit or a tax rebate 
or whatever, you are going to spend nearly all of it; whereas, 
if you are really in good shape, and you are high on the income 
scale, you are likely to bank most of a tax rebate check or 
whatever you get. So we do have this coincidence that the items 
that are most effective as stimulus also have the effect of 
helping the people who are in the most trouble.
    I would also note that the unemployment insurance in food 
stamp provisions tend to have the effect of targeting regions 
that are in the most trouble. Obviously, if a particular area--
a particular set of States has their economy go way down and 
their unemployment rate go way up, they are going to have a 
larger percentage increase in the proportion of their labor 
force that is unemployed and that will benefit from 
unemployment benefits, and those benefits will be spent in the 
local economy. Similarly, food stamp caseloads will increase 
more in parts of the country where the economy is weak than in 
parts of the country where it stays strong. So you kind of get 
a natural targeting effect as well in terms of areas of the 
country.
    Ms. Kaptur. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, very much.
    Chairman Spratt. Mr. Ryan has one final question to ask for 
clarification.
    Mr. Ryan. Well, I know you wanted to hit the gavel at 1:00. 
I guess I will just do this very quickly.
    Mr. Cooper had a line of questioning that was very 
interesting. I wanted to follow up on it and see if there is a 
consensus here.
    Putting political realities aside, going down in the 
century, looking at the trend lines, which is--our historic tax 
slice of GDP is 18.3 over the 40-year number, and I think the 
50-year number is 18.1 percent of GDP.
    Is it not dangerous for our economy, for our future living 
standards to pierce that 20 percent level, and given that 
entitlements are taking us up to, I think, 40 percent of GDP 
midcentury, 2040--that's the GAO's number--is it better to try 
and get that expenditure line down to the revenue line at sub 
20 percent, or should we just allow the revenue line to go up 
to that 40 percent GDP expenditure line? And let us just go 
from left to right, which is your right to left. Curious.
    Mr. Summers. I don't think there is any magic level of 20 
percent at which danger is--in which danger comes to the 
economy. I think the entitlements issue, as the tone of your 
question suggests, is a very serious one, and I suspect that 
the necessary way to address it will involve reforms on both 
the expenditure side, as you suggest, and on the revenue side.
    Mr. Ryan. My basic question is: Where is that turning 
point? Is there a turning point, in your mind, at 22 percent of 
GDP, 24, 30?
    Mr. Summers. Clearly as you raise tax burdens, potential 
inefficiencies associated with taxes rise. Clearly as you fall 
further and further short of providing healthcare to people of 
the kind that technology makes available, the losses to the 
economy from those failed opportunities rise.
    There is a balance that has to be struck. It probably has 
to be struck differently for every generation, and it is the 
task of our elected leaders to strike that balance. But, I 
think, thinking in terms of danger points is almost certainly a 
serious mistake. I would not for a moment recommend it to the 
United States, but there are a number of countries that have 
enjoyed economic growth as rapidly as ours and have enjoyed 
unemployment rates as low or lower than ours who have tax 
shares of GNP of 30 or 35 or even more percent. I think that 
would be wrong for the United States, but I think any effort to 
suggest that there is some danger point over which we head into 
some abyss of stagnation is extremely misleading.
    Mr. Ryan. Dr. Rivlin.
    Ms. Rivlin. I agree with that. I don't think there is a 
magic number on how much of the GDP you devote to government, 
but what is magic is that you pay for it over the long run, and 
we have not been. As the Chairman noted earlier, we have been 
running deficits in the range of 2 percent of GDP for a long 
time on the average, but now we are headed into a really 
dangerous area where, if we don't change course, they go up to 
5, 6, 10, whatever. So we just have to decide how much do we 
want to spend, and how much do we want to tax.
    And then the other point I would add to what Professor 
Summers said is it matters how you tax, and we should be 
thinking very seriously about reforming our tax system and, I 
think, putting less reliance on the income tax and more 
reliance on consumer taxation.
    Mr. Ryan. Mr. Greenstein.
    Mr. Greenstein. Sir, you kind of asked--you have got these 
two lines--the spending line and the revenue line. Do you bring 
one down to the other or the revenue line up to the spending? 
Neither one is going to be politically feasible or is going to 
work. We are going to have to both bring the spending line down 
and bring the revenue line up.
    And to build on what Alice just said, it not only matters 
how you tax, the composition of spending also matters. If you 
stay at 18\1/2\ percent of GDP, and as a result of that we 
underinvest in education and the infrastructure crumbles, that 
has significant economic effects.
    It seems to me that, if we are talking about the danger 
area, the danger that underlies all of this is we will not be 
able to bring those two lines in future decades remotely close 
to each other unless we have some kind of systemwide healthcare 
reform, because the single biggest issue here--as I know, Peter 
Orszag has testified before the committee--are the projected 
rates of growth in healthcare costs systemwide. It is not 
something unique to Medicare and Medicaid; it is system-wide 
rates of healthcare cost growth, and if we don't address those, 
they not only affect the Federal budget, they affect employers 
as well in the private economy. So----
    Mr. Ryan. Thank you. I think we can agree on that one.
    Mr. Wesbury. Final.
    Mr. Wesbury. Yes. I agree as well that there is no magic 
level of government spending that--or government taxation that 
always precedes a recession. We have had many recessions with 
tax receipts at 15, 16, 17 percent of GDP.
    However, I would suggest that we have had two periods of 
time where tax receipts went above 20, and in both of those 
times, we had recessions, the latest being in 2001.
    The long-term average--about a 50-year average--of tax 
receipts is 18.1 percent of GDP. Today we are at 18.4, which is 
kind of interesting for those people who say lower tax rates 
don't generate revenues. They are. They are generating, in 
fact, more than the long-run average of revenues to the Federal 
Government as a share of GDP.
    It is very clear to me, looking throughout history, that 
rising tax burdens, especially the tax rates--it is not always 
tax revenues that we should focus on--tax rates inhibit growth.
    And then one last point. When Dr. Summers brought up the 
fact that other countries have operated at 34 or 35 percent tax 
rates, we have that in the United States. If you add State and 
local and Federal tax burdens along with the burdens of 
regulation, we are at a 35 to 40 percent burden on the private 
sector today, and so we are operating. The problem becomes when 
we go out into the future. The cost of entitlement programs 
rises, and if we were to increase tax rates to pay for that, I 
believe we would harm our economy just like we have done in the 
past.
    Mr. Ryan. Thank you.
    Chairman Spratt. This concludes the hearing. I want to 
thank our witnesses for coming and for your clear, forthright 
and very useful answers.
    I would ask unanimous consent that any Members who did not 
have an opportunity, to be able to submit questions for the 
record within 7 days.
    Thank you very much for coming. Thank you very much, 
indeed.
    [Whereupon, at 1:08 p.m., the committee was adjourned.]